Issue no. 52, 10 March 2010
Issue no. 51, 1 December 2009
Issue no. 50, 8 September 2009
Issue no. 49, 12 March 2009
Issue no. 48, 6 December 2008
Issue no. 47, 3 October 2008
issue
46
issue
45
issue
44
issue 43
issue 42
issue 41
issue 40
issue 39
issue 38
issue 37
issue
36
issue 35
issue 34
issue 33
issue 32
issue 31
issue 30
issue 29
issue 28
issue 27
issue 26
issue 25
issue 24
issue 23
issue 22
issue 21
issue 20
issue 19
issue 18
issue 17
issue 16
issue 15
issue
14
issue
13
issue
12
issue
11
issue
10
issue 9
issue 8
issue 7
issue 6
issue 5
issue 4
issue 3
Issue no. 2, 3 October 2000
Issue no. 1, September 2000
|
ToxicTextbooks.com
Toxic
Textbooks Facebook Group
The
Post-Autistic Economics Movement - A brief history
The
Strange History of Economics
Policy
Implications of Post-Autistic Economics
Network Resources
Some articles on the PAE Movement
Teaching
Economics: PAE and Pluralism,(EAEPE, July 2005)
Post-Autistic
Economics (SocialPolicy, summer 2005)
Post-Autistic
Economics (Soundings, April 2005)
Signifying
nothing?(The Economist, Jan 29, 2004)
Revolutionizing
French Economics(Challenge, Nov/Dec. 2003) pdf
Fired up for
battle (The Guardian, (UK) 9 September 2003
Taking On
'Rational Man' (The Chronicle of Higher Education, (US) 24 Jan.
2003)
The 2002
Nobel Prize in Economics (The Journal of Investing, (US) Spring 2003
The
Storming of the Accountants The New Statesman, (UK) 21 Jan. 2002
Post-autisten
vallen economische heilige huisjes aan De Morgen (Bruxelles,) 2
Mar. 2002 - English
Translation
“movimiento
económico postautista” IBLNEWS, 14 March 2002
Distorted
economic relations: A new movement – the post-autistic economists
- want to renew economics” Sueddeutsche
Zeitung (Munich), 3 April 2002
Some important PAE texts
The Student
Petition of Autisme-Economie (June 2000)
French
Petition for a Debate on the Teaching of Economics July 2000)
Issue
No. 1 of the post-autistic economics newsletter ( September
2000)
A
Contribution on the State of Economics in France and the World,
James K. Galbraith,
January 2001
Humility
in Economics, André Orléan
Real Science is
Pluralist, Edward Fullbrook
Teaching
Economics Through Controversies Gilles Raveaud
Back
to Reality, Tony Lawson
The
Relevance of Controversies for Practice as Well as Teaching, Sheila
C Dow
Opening Up
Economics, The Cambridge 27
Economists
Have No Ears, Steve Keen
An International
Open Letter, The Kansas City Proposal
How
Did Economics Get Into Such a State?, Geoffrey Hodgson
Why
the PAE Movement Needs Feminism, Julie A. Nelson
Kicking
Away the Ladder: How the Economic and
Intellectual Histories of Capitalism Have Been Re-Written to Justify
Neo-Liberal Capitalism, Ha-Joon Chang
Economic
History and the Rebirth of Respectable Characters, Stephen T. Ziliak
Some
Old But Good Ideas, Anne Mayhew
An
Alternative Framework for Economics, Jason Potts and John
Nightingale
Is
the Concept of Economic Growth Autistic?, Jean Gadrey
Toward
a Post-Autistic Economics Education, Susan Feiner
Is
There Anything Worth Keeping in Standard Microeconomics?, Bernard
Guerrien
Doctrine-centered
Versus Problem-centered Economics, Peter Dorman
Social
Being as a Problem for an Ethical Economics, Jamie Morgan
The
Petitions
New Petition, (May 2008)
Student
Essays on PAE
Two
World Views: Ecological Economics vs. Environmental Economics
German Section - French
Section - Portuguese
Section - Spanish
Section - Chinese,
Flemish, Italian and Turkish Sections
The
Perestroika Movement - a
sister movement to PAE in
political science
Miscellaneous
Some
more articles concerning the PAE Movement
New
Post-Autistic Economics Books
A
Brief History of the Post-Autistic Economics Movement
Theories, scientific and
otherwise, do not represent the world as it is but rather by
highlighting
certain aspects of it while leaving others in the dark.
It may be the case that two theories highlight
the same aspects of some
corner of reality but offer different conclusions.
In the last century, this type of situation
preoccupied the philosophy of
science. Post-Autistic
Economics, however, addresses a different kind of situation: one
where one
theory, that illuminates a few facets of its domain rather well, wants
to
suppress other theories that would illuminate some of the many facets
that it
leaves in the dark. This theory is
neoclassical economics. Because it
has been so successful at sidelining other approaches, it also is
called
“mainstream economics”.
From the 1960s onward,
neoclassical economists have increasingly managed to block the
employment of
non-neoclassical economists in university economics departments and to
deny them
opportunities to publish in professional journals.
They also have narrowed the economics
curriculum that universities offer
students. At the same time they
have increasingly formalized their theory, making it progressively
irrelevant to
understanding economic reality. And
now they are even banishing economic history and the history of
economic thought
from the curriculum, these being places where the student might be
exposed to
non-neoclassical ideas. Why has
this tragedy happened?
Many factors have
contributed,
but three especially. First,
neoclassical economists have as a group deluded themselves into
believing that
all you need for an exact science is mathematics, and never mind about
whether
the symbols used refer quantitatively to the real world.
What began as an indulgence became an
addiction, leading to a collective
fantasy of scientific achievement where in most cases none exists.
To preserve their illusions, neoclassical
economists have found it
increasingly necessary to isolate themselves from non-believers.
Second, as Joseph Stiglitz
has observed, economics has suffered “a triumph of ideology over
science”.1
Instead of regarding their theory as a tool in
the pursuit of knowledge,
neoclassical economists have made it the required viewpoint from which,
at all
times and in all places, to look at all economic phenomena.
This is the position of neoliberalism.
Third, today’s economies,
including the societies in which they are embedded, are very different
from
those of the 19th century for which neoclassical economics
was
invented to describe. These
differences become more pronounced every decade as new aspects of
economic
reality emerge, for example, consumer societies, corporate
globalization,
economic induced environmental disasters and impending ecological ones,
the
accelerating gap between the rich and poor, and the movement for
equal-opportunity economies. Consequently
neoclassical economics sheds light on an ever-smaller proportion of
economic
reality, leaving more and more of it in the dark for students permitted
only the
neoclassical viewpoint. This makes
the neoclassical monopoly more outrageous and costly every year,
requiring of it
ever more desperate measures of defense, like eliminating economic
history and
history of economics from the curriculum.
But eventually reality overtakes time-warp
worlds like
mainstream economics and the Soviet Union.
The moment and place of the tipping point,
however, nearly always takes
people by surprise. In June 2000
.................... more
_______________________________________________
The
Strange History of Economics
These days
people like to call neoclassical economics “mainstream economics”
because
most universities offer nothing else. The
name also backhandedly stigmatizes as oddball, flaky, deviant,
disreputable,
perhaps un-American those economists who venture beyond the narrow
confines of
the neoclassical axioms. To
understand the powerful attraction of those axioms one must know a
little about
their origins. They are not what an
outsider might think. Although
today neoclassical economics cavorts with neoliberalism,
it began as a honest intellectual and
would-be
scientific endeavour. Its patron
saint was neither an ideologue nor a political philosopher nor even an
economist, but Sir Isaac Newton. The
founding fathers of neoclassical economics hoped to achieve, and their
descendents living today believe they have, for the economic universe
what
Newton had achieved for the physical universe.
This brief article roughly
traces the strange history of economics from the 1870s through to the
beginning
of Post-Autistic Economics movement in the summer of 2000.
.................... more
_____________________________________________
Policy
Implications of Post-Autistic Economics
The
neoclassical monopoly in the classroom and its prohibition on critical
thinking
means that it brainwashes successive generations of students into
viewing
economic reality exclusively through its concepts, which more often
than not
misrepresent or veil the world, especially today’s world.
Nearly all of these neoclassical notions have
a bearing on judgements
about social, cultural and economic policy.
Consequently, if society were to learn to
think about economic matters
outside the neoclassical conceptual system, it would almost certainly
choose
different policies. One of Post-Autistic
Economics’
(
PAE
) projects
has been to expose some of the many conceptual lunacies
of today’s mainstream, both in terms of the concepts it uses and the
concepts
it lacks. Drawing on recent essays
by
PAE
economists in A Guide to What’s
Wrong with Economics, especially the chapters by Michael A.
Bernstein, Geoffrey Hodgson, Peter Söderbaum,
Hugh Stretton,
Richard Wolff, Robert Costanza,
Herman E. Daly, Jean Gadrey and Edward
Fullbrook,*
this brief article briefly considers ten such concepts.
Neoclassical
economics regards competition as a state rather than as a
process.
It defines perfect competition as a market
with a large number of firms
with identical products, costs structures, production
techniques and
market information. But in real
life competition is a process by which firms continually seek to
re-establish
the conditions of their own profitability.
To compete in a market requires firms to seek
out and exploit differences
between them in production, technology, distribution, access to
information and
awareness of trends in consumption. These
differences are the essential dimensions in which competition takes
place.
Once the neoclassical conception of
competition becomes imbedded in the
student’s mind, appreciation of real-world competition, and hence the
policies
that might enhance it, becomes logically impossible.
Neoclassical
economists love to talk about freedom of choice.
But this is pure rhetoric, because they define
rationality in a way that
eliminates free choice from their conceptual space.
By rationality they mean that an agent’s
choices are in conformity with
an ordering or scale of preferences. The
“rational” agent chooses among the alternatives available that one
which is
highest on his ranking. Rational
behaviour simply means behaviour in accordance with some ordering of
alternatives in terms of relative desirability.
In order for this approach to have any
predictive power, it must be
assumed that the preferences do not change over some period of time.
So the basic condition of
neoclassical rationality is that individuals must forego choice
in favour
of some past reckoning, thereafter acting as automata.
This conceptual elimination of freedom of
choice, in both its everyday
and philosophical meanings, gives neoclassical theory the hypothetical
determinacy that its Newtonian inspired metaphysics require.
No indeterminacy; no choice.
No
determinacy; no neoclassical model. This
is far from just an academic matter, because society needs an economics
that is
able to address questions regarding freedom of choice.
No
terms in neoclassical economics are more sacrosanct than rational
choice
and rationality. Everyone
identities with these words, because everyone wants to think of
themselves as
rational. But few people realize
that economists give these words an ultra eccentric meaning.
Neoclassical economics begins with an a
priori conception of
markets and economies as determinate systems that by the action of
individual
agents alone tend toward an efficient and market-clearing equilibrium.
This requires that the individual agents, like
the bodies in Newton’s
system, behave in a prescribed manner. Neoclassicalists
have deduced the particular pattern of behaviour that would make their
imagined
world logically possible, then named it “rational choice” or
“rationality” and then declared that that is the way real people behave.
But thankfully they don’t.
Everyday
economic actors do many things that by the neoclassical meaning of
“rational” are “irrational”.
Looking to the choices of other consumers as
guides to what one might
buy; buying a stock because you believe other people will be buying it
and so
increase its value, spending your money in a spirit of spontaneity
rather than
stopping to calculate the consequences and alternatives up to the
limits of your
cognitive powers; a taste for change, that is, buying something because
you did
not previously prefer it; these common consumer behaviours are all
prohibited
under the neoclassical notions of rational choice and rationality and
so outside
its scope of analysis.
These
failings connect with another. Neoclassical
economics is by its own axioms incapable of offering a coherent
conceptualisation of the individual or economic agent.
From where do the preferences that supposedly
dictate the individual’s
choice come from? Not from
interpersonal relations, because if individual demands were
interdependent, they
would not be additive and thus the market demand function – neoclassicalism’s
key analytical tool – would be undefined.
And not from society, because neoclassicalism’s
Newtonian atomism translates as methodological individualism, meaning
that
society is to be explained in terms of individuals and never the other
way
around.
This
leaves an awful lot in the dark. In
the main, despite the neoclassical axioms, we all categorise and
classify
according to prevailing cultural norms. Likewise
our tastes and preferences for this and that reflect the social
conventions and
institutions with which we interact. Consequently
individual choice is unavoidably and inextricably bound up with
historically and
geographically given social worlds. An
economics that has nothing to say about the formation of economic
tastes and
preferences is silly and irresponsible, especially in an age of
consumer
societies and in a world now threatened with climate-change or worse.
For half a century neoclassical economics has hid its ideology behind
the notion
that it calls positive economics. This
is the idea that it contains no value judgements because it mentions
none.
Of course such a notion belongs to an
intellectually more naive age than
today, but nonetheless it persists as an effective tool of
indoctrination of
undergraduates. The fact that
neoclassical economics requires a highly restricted focus in order to
maintain
its atomist and determinist metaphysics compels it to make many extreme
judgements about what is and is not economically important.
There is not space even to list them.
But an example is its notion of
“economic man”, which is acutely
ideological, as it emphasizes
some roles and relationships and excludes others.
By allowing only decisions based on utility
maximization, it excludes
other forms of ethics. As an
economic agent, each individual acts in many roles, not just market
ones, and is
guided by his or her “ideological orientation”.
That orientation may be founded on
utilitarianism or not.
It may for example be based on social and
environmental ethics.
PAE
economists do not believe that
economists have the right to select one ethics as the “correct” one for
framing economic analysis. Furthermore
the neoclassical insistence upon the utilitarian ideology legitimises a
kind of
“market ideology” and “consumerism” that increasingly appears dangerous
to society and sidelines the debate about Sustainable Development.
Like rationality, nearly everyone thinks efficiency is a good
idea.
Neoclassical economists adore using this word,
especially when addressing
the public. But the meaning of
“efficiency” always depends on what you choose to count.
For example, ..............
more
|