WIDER Jubilee
Conference. Helsinki, Finland, June 2005.
WIDER
Thinking Ahead: the Future of Development Economics |
Themes
addressed in this conference:
- Institutions and
Governance - Conflict and Human Rights
- Development Finance
- Development Economics in Retrospect
- Poverty and Vulnerability - Foreign Aid
- Development Strategies - China - Globalization
- A New World Economic Order - Behavioural Approaches
- Poverty - Wellbeing and Human Development
- Trade and Development - Migration and Employment
- Africa - International Finance - Pro-poor Policies
- Technology and Development - Informal Sector
- Rural Development - Achieving the MDGs - Growth
- Country Strategies - Cultural and Social Capital
Conference
papers:
|
Keynotes
|
Global inequalities in
long term perspective
Richard Jolly - 2005
Adam Smith’s emphasis on the central
importance for development of the
division of labour is often repeated. Less well known is what he had to
say about inequality and its origins. Smith was blunt:
"Wherever there is great property, there is great inequality. For
one very rich
man there must be at least five hundred poor, and the affluence of the
few supposes
the indigence of the many".
Smith also emphasized the way such inequality led on to the need for
government to maintain law and order.
“The affluence of the rich excites the indignation of the poor, who
are often
both driven by want, and prompted by envy, to invade his possessions.
It is
only under the shelter of the civil magistrate that the owner of that
valuable
property…can sleep at night in security…The acquisition of valuable and
extensive property, therefore, necessarily requires the establishment
of civil
government."
Smith had an evolutionary view of society and made clear how inequality
evolved with property. In hunter society, the first period of society,
there
was little property and little inequality – and with contemporary
understanding, probably less true than Smith thought – seldom any
regular administration of justice. The second period of society was the
‘age of shepherds’ and with this “the inequality of fortune first
begins to
take place and introduces among men a degree of authority and
subordination which could not possibly exist before. It thereby
introduces
some degree of civil government which is indispensably necessary for
its
own preservation.”
Smith though blunt, was measured. Thomas Paine writing two decades
later also focused on land as the source of inequality, but he
presented his
analysis with pre-Marxian vitriol.
“It is very well known that in England (and the same will be found
in other
countries) the great landed estates, now held in descent, were
plundered from
the quiet inhabitants at the conquest. The possibility did not exist of
acquiring
such estates honestly…That they were not acquired by trade, by
commerce, by
manufactures, by agriculture or by any reputable employment is certain.
How
then were they acquired? Blush, aristocracy, to hear your origin, for
your
progenitors were Thieves…When they had committed the robbery, they
endeavoured to lose the disgrace of it, by sinking their real names
under
fictious ones, which they called Titles. It is ever the practice of
Felons to act in
this manner.” (Thomas Paine, Dissertations on First Principles, in Rights of Man, Common Sense and other political
writings (Oxford, Oxford University Press) 1995, p 401.)
|
The pace and
distribution of health improvements during the last 40 years: some
preliminary results
Giovanni Andrea Cornia and Leonardo Menchini - 2005
This paper juxtaposes changes over
the last forty years in indicators of income growth and
distribution with the mortality changes recorded at the aggregate level
in about 170 countries and at the
individual level in 21 countries with at least two Demographic and
Health Surveys covering the last twenty
years. Over the 1980s-and 1990s, the infant-mortality rate (IMR),
under-5 mortality rate (U5MR) and Life
Expectancy at Birth (LEB) mostly continued the favourable trends that
characterized the 1960s and 1970s.
Yet, especially, the 1990s the pace of health improvement was slower
than that recorded during the prior
decades. In addition, the distribution between countries of aggregate
health improvements became
markedly more skewed. These trends are in part explained by the
negative changes recorded in Sub-
Saharan Africa and Eastern Europe, but are robust to the removal of the
two regions from the sample. This
tendency is observed also at the intra-regional level, with the
exception of Western Europe. Thirdly, DHS
data for 21 developing countries point to a frequent divergence over
time in the within-country distribution
of gains in IMR and U5MR among children living in urban vs. rural areas
and belonging to families part of
different quantiles of the asset distribution, while IMR differentials
by level of education of the mother
show mixed trends The paper concludes by underscoring the similarities
and linkages between changes in
income inequality and health inequality and suggests some tentative
explanations of these trends without,
however, formally testing them.
|
Inequality values and
unequal shares
Tony Shorrocks - 2005
One of the great handicaps faced by researchers on
inequality is the difficulty of
conveying the significance of summary measures of inequality to a broad
audience, especially
non-economists. While concepts such as unemployment, inflation, growth,
productivity and
poverty can be grasped intuitively by the general public—although not
with all the fine nuances
—this is not the case with inequality values. The increasing attention
given to issues concerning
population heterogeneity has made the lack of an intuitive concept a
more pressing problem. This
perhaps explains a growing tendency to revert to the use of crude
measures of inequality, such
as the inter-decile ratio.
The Gini coefficient is the summary measure which comes closest to
providing an
intuitive interpretation. Indeed, this is the main reason why the Gini
coefficient remains by far
the most popular inequality index.1 Yet the standard interpretations of
the Gini coefficient fall
far short of immediate comprehension. The most common interpretation is
the area above the
curve in a Lorenz diagram expressed as a proportion of the area below
the diagonal; but this
presupposes familiarity with the notion of a Lorenz curve. The Gini can
also be defined in terms
of the average absolute difference between incomes in the population,
sampling randomly with
replacement over the entire population. In fact Yitzhaki (1998) lists
more than 12 alternative
ways of defining the Gini coefficient—“spelling Gini” is how he puts
it. However none of these
linguistic variations succeed in providing the simple intuitive concept
that everyone craves.
|
Trends in income
inequality: a critical examination of the evidence in WIID2
2005 Markus Jantti and Susanna Sandstrom - 2005
This paper examines changes across
time in within-country inequality using the most recent, and
we would argue, the most appropriate data at hand, the updated World
Income Inequality Database
(WIID2). We attempt to find whether it is possible to find robust
evidence on inequality trends.
Our empirical approach is to use so-called mixed-effects models with
quintile groups means as the
dependent variable, observed covariates as explanatory variables and
allow for (at the most detailed
level) country-specific intercepts and trends. This statistical
framework allows us to assess in a
structured fashion the actual patterns of inequality change across the
world and to start to examine
if these changes can be accounted for by readily observable economic
and demographic factors.
|
2.2
INSTITUTIONS AND GOVERNANCE
|
Understanding the
relationship between institutions and economic development...
Ha-Joon Chang - 2005
The issue of institutional
development, or “governance reform”, has come to
prominence during the last several years. During this period, the
academic literature on
institutions and development has exploded. And today even the World
Bank and the IMF,
which used to dismiss institutions as mere “details” that do not affect
the wisdom of the
orthodox economic theory, have come around to emphasising the role of
institutions in
economic development. For example, the International Monetary Fund
(IMF) put great
emphasis on reforming corporate governance institutions and bankruptcy
laws during the
1997 Asian crisis, while the World Bank’s recent annual report
(Building Institutions for
Markets, 2002) focuses on institutional development, although from a
rather narrow point of
view, as indicated by its title.
|
Institutions, policies
and economic development
Grzegorz Kolodko - 2005
Institutions are not only created and
built, but also – and especially – need to be learnt.
It is a process which takes place in all economies, but acquires a
special importance in less
advanced countries. Not only theoretical arguments, but also the
practical experience over the
past 15 years demonstrate that faster economic growth – and hence also,
more broadly, socioeconomic
development – is attained by those countries which take greater care to
foster the
institutional reinforcement of market economy. However, progress in
market-economy
institution building is not in itself sufficient to ensure sustained
growth. Another
indispensable component is an appropriately designed and implemented
economic policy
which must not confuse the means with the aims.
|
Governance in
decentralized development aid programs
Frédéric Gaspart and Jean-Philippe Platteau - 2005
Largely as a response to critiques of
top-down development and of a
growing awareness of the low effectiveness of aid absorption in poor
countries, the
international donor community has recently adopted with enthusiasm and
determination a
new approach to fight poverty, called the community-based development
approach (CBD).
Such an abrupt shift in aid strategies is questionable, not because the
approach is wrong (the
opposite is actually the case), but because massive injections of aid
funds in CBD projects,
the entry into the field of numerous agencies with little or no
experience in participatory
development, as well as the pressing need for quick and visible
results, threaten to undermine
its effectiveness in reducing poverty. The cause for worry comes from
the ‘elite capture’
problem that risks deflecting a large portion of the resources devoted
to CBD into the hands
of powerful groups dominating target communities. On the basis of a
game-theoretical
model, the main aim of the paper is to discuss the use of sequential
and conditional
disbursement procedures as a way of surmounting such a problem, and to
examine how the
share of CBD aid reaching the poor is influenced by various elements of
the aid environment,
including the pressure of competition among donor agencies and the
availability of aid funds.
Multilateral reputation mechanisms and intra-community competition for
leadership are also
assessed as possible alternatives to sequential disbursement
procedures.
|
Corruptibility,
transparency, and bureaucratic institutional structure
John Bennett and Saul Estrin - 2005
We analyze the role of bureaucratic
corruption in the context of infrastructure
investment and public service provision by a foreign firm in a
developing economy.
This type of investment involves a relatively large sunk element, and
so the investor
may offer a bribe to avoid expropriation, as well as to obtain more
favourable terms in
the initial contract. We examine these issues for both a centralized
and a decentralized
bureaucracy, and we consider the role of transparency in each case.
Among our results
is that, provided there is transparency, domestic welfare and social
efficiency may be
enhanced by decentralization. The key factor underlying this result is
that one
bureaucrat in effect may collude with the investor to reduce the payoff
of another
bureaucrat.
|
2.3 CONFLICT AND HUMAN RIGHTS
|
Inequality,
indivisibility and insecurity (PDF 73KB)
Mansoob Murshed
Civil war and organised collective
violence is a complex phenomenon. Not only does
it produce human tragedies on a colossal scale, but it creates
humanitarian crises that
are of concern to the international community, as well as contributing
to global and
regional insecurity. To economists, especially development economists,
civil war is
important as it is now recognised as a major cause of underdevelopment
and the
persistence of poverty (see Murshed, 2002a; Collier et. Al. 2003). The
number of
countries embroiled in a civil war seems to have waned after 1994
(Hegre, 2004). The
number of new civil wars emerging also seems to have fallen in the last
decade
(Hegre, 2004). But the average duration of civil wars, standing at 16
years in 1999,
does not seem to exhibit a significant downward trend (Fearon, 2004).
The number of
fatalities in civil war may be declining recently, but the numbers of
refugees and
internally displaced persons is rising (Human Security Report, 2005).
For all of these
reasons ending conflict or reducing its intensity must be a very high
policy imperative
within the development and international security agenda.
Inequality in Historical
Perspective
Richard Jolly - 2006
Adam
Smith, Tom Paine, John Stuart Mill and Karl Marx were all bold and
outspoken
about the injustices of extreme inequality, nationally and
internationally. Yet by almost
every standard, global inequality has grown substantially since they
were writing, and
national income inequality also over the last two or three decades.
There is a case today
for more outspokenness about the extremes of inequality, both about the
causes and how
these causes are linked to extreme injustices in the past.
|
Bilateral war in a multilateral world: carrots and sticks for
conflict resolution (PDF 188KB) -
Zsolt Becsi and Sajal Lahiri
This paper constructs a
three-country, many-good and many-factor trade-theoretic model
in which two of the countries are in conflict and where war effort is
determined endogenously
in a Nash equilibrium. The third country does not take part in the war,
but trades with
the warring countries. In the framework, we examine, inter alia, how
war and welfare are
affected by globalization and by two instruments available to the third
country — one carrot
and one stick. Our overall conclusion is that the third parties do have
the incentives for, and
can play an effective role in, conflict resolution.
|
Globalization and human rights approach to
development
Siddiq Osmani - 2007
Would globalization enhance the
implementation of human rights as stated in the Universal Declaration
of Human Rights ( 1948 ) and the subsequent United Nations agreements ,
particularly the covenant on civil and political rights ( 1966 ) ,the
covenant on economic, social and cultural rights (1966 ) and the
declaration on the right to development (1986 ).?
Attempting an answer to this question is not an easy task, mainly
because of the different and contradictory connotations of the term
globalization.
|
Violence in peace,
understanding increased violence in early post-conflict transitions and
its implications for development
Marcia Hartwell
A key issue for development in the
late twentieth and early twenty-first centuries has
been an escalation of violence during post-conflict transitions. A
long-term goal for
international donor involvement is to assist in building legitimate and
effective political,
economic, and legal institutions. However, research and observation has
revealed that
increased violence is commonplace during peace processes and strongly
influences the
ways in which these institutions are formed. In turn post-conflict
violence itself is
strongly influenced and motivated by the way in which peace agreements
have been
negotiated. This study addresses some of the reasons for escalation of
violence
following peace agreements. It describes the underlying dynamics
including the
relationship between perceptions of justice as fairness, formation of
post-conflict
identity, political processes of forgiveness and revenge; and the
policy implications for
development particularly in relation to peace conditionality tied to
aid.
|
2.4
DEVELOPMENT FINANCE
|
Capital flows to the
African continent: the development finance challenge
Elsabe Loots
In the 1960s and early 1970s Africa’s
future looked bright and promising. Economic
growth and development on the continent was considerably higher than in
other
developing regions. However, during the middle 1970s political
instability increased and
economic development started to deteriorate, both contributing to the
marginalization of
the continent. The continued marginalization constitutes a serious
threat to Africa’s
participation in the global economy. Nepad calls for a reversal of this
process through a
new partnership between Africa and the international community (Nepad,
2001: 1 & 2).
The Nepad document (2001:10), within the context of the United Nations
Millennium
Declaration adopted in September 2000, recognizes the fact that the
continent’s
underdevelopment and marginalization could be addressed by improvements
in trade, aid
and capital flows. To achieve the outcomes of Nepad and the UN
millennium goals,
quantitative goals are set such as the achievement of an average annual
economic growth
rate of 7 per cent per annum to fill the annual resource gap of US$ 64
billion (Nepad,
2001:36). Although it is recognized that the so-called resource gap
could partly be filled
by increases in domestic savings and improvements in public revenue
collection, the bulk
of the needed resources would have to be obtained from external
sources, and in
particular debt relief as well as increases in aid, trade and FDI
flows.
|
East
Asian Regional Architecture: New Economic
and Security Arrangements and U.S. Policy
Dick K. Nanto - Specialist in Industry and Trade
Updated January 4, 2008
U.S. Congress' Foreign Affairs, Defense, and Trade Division
The end of the Cold War, the rise of
China, globalization, free trade agreements,
the war on terror, and an institutional approach to keeping the peace
are causing
dramatic shifts in relationships among countries in East Asia. A new
regional
architecture in the form of trade, financial, and political
arrangements among
countries of East Asia is developing that has significant implications
for U.S.
interests and policy. This report examines this regional architecture
with a focus on
China, South Korea, Japan, and Southeast Asia. The types of
arrangements include
bilateral free trade agreements (FTAs), regional trade pacts, currency
and monetary
arrangements, and political and security arrangements.
The East Asian regional architecture is supported by two distinct legs.
The
economic leg is strong and growing more intense. A web of bilateral and
regional
FTAs is developing. An East Asian Economic Community (with 13 nations),
an East
Asian FTA (with 16 nations), and an Asia Pacific FTA (with 21 nations)
are being
discussed. In contrast, the political and security leg remains
relatively
underdeveloped. The most progress has been made with the Association of
South
East Asian Nations playing the role of convener and has taken the form
of the
ASEAN Security Community (10 Southeast Asian nations) and ASEAN
Regional
Forum (25 nations, including the United States). In Northeast Asia, the
six-party
talks aimed at resolving the North Korean nuclear program are ongoing.
|
IMF concern for
reputation and conditional lending failure: theory and empirics
Silvia Marchesi and Laura Sabani
In this paper we suggest that the
dual role played by the IMF, as a creditor and as a monitor of economic
reforms, might explain the lack of credibility of the Fund threat of
sanctioning non-compliance with conditionality. Specifically, we show
that the IMF's desire to preserve its reputation as a good monitor may
distort its lending decisions towards some laxity. Moreover, such
distortionary incentives may be exacerbated by the length of the
relationship between a country and the Fund. Estimating a dynamic panel
of 53 middle-income countries, for the period 1982–2001, we find that a
longer relationship does increase IMF disbursements.
|
The
determinants of foreign direct investment restrictive policies
Hadi Esfahani - 2005
This paper examines the determinants
of FDI employment restrictions. We construct a political economy
model where the TNE and the government have different objective
functions: the TNE maximizes profits,
and the host government cares about tax revenue and local employment.
We show that the level of
employment preferred by the government exceeds the level preferred by
the TNE — the divergence in
preferences motivates the government to impose restrictions. We test
the implications of the model using
data on employment restrictions derived from the World Bank’s World
Business Environment Survey,
conducted in 1999/2000. The analysis employs data for up to 1207
foreign-owned firms operating in 52
countries.
|
3.1
DEVELOPMENT ECONOMICS IN RETROSPECT
|
The
evolution of the development doctrine and the role of foreign aid,
1950-2005
Erik Thorbecke
The economic and social development of the third world,
as such, was clearly not a
policy objective of the colonial rulers before the Second World Wari.
Such an objective
would have been inconsistent with the underlying division of labour and
trading patterns
within and among colonial blocks. It was not until the end of the
colonial system in the
late forties and fifties, and the subsequent creation of independent
states, that the
revolution of rising expectations could start. Thus, the end of Second
World War
marked the beginning of a new regime for the less developed countries
involving the
evolution from symbiotic to inward-looking growth and from a dependent
to a
somewhat more independent relation vis-à-vis the ex-colonial powers. It
also marked
the beginning of serious interest among scholars and policymakers in
studying and
understanding better the development process as a basis for designing
appropriate
development policies and strategies. In a broad sense a conceptual
development doctrine
had to be built which policymakers in the newly independent countries
could use as a
guideline to the formulation of economic policies.
|
From Seers to Sen: the
meaning of economic development
Wayne E. Nafziger - 2005
How has the meaning of economic
development changed during the twenty years of
WIDER’s existence? Two markers are Dudley Seers, “The Meaning of
Development”
(1967, 1979), for the earlier period and Amartya Sen, Development as
Freedom (1999),
for the later. Here the meaning of development also encompasses
measures and strategies
of development and approaches to its study. Moreover, I examine works
beyond these
markers to provide more detail of the two men’s views.
Both men were critical of the development literature of their times.
For Seers,
neoclassical economics had a flawed paradigm and dependency theory a
lack of policy
realism. After the fall of state socialism in 1989-1991, the
ideological struggles among
economists diminished. Neoclassicism’s Washington Consensus of the
World Bank,
IMF, and the U.S. government reigned (Williamson 1993, pp. 1329-1336;
1994, pp. 26-
28). Sen did not focus on ideological issues but, according to the
Nobel prize committee,
“restored an ethical dimension to the discussion of economic problems”
such as
development.
According to Seers (1979) the purpose of development is to reduce
poverty,
inequality, and unemployment. For Sen (1999), development involves
reducing
deprivation or broadening choice. Deprivation represents a
multidimensional view of
poverty that includes hunger, illiteracy, illness and poor health,
powerlessness,
voicelessness, insecurity, humiliation, and a lack of access to basic
infrastructure
(Narayan et al. 2000, pp. 4-5).
|
Kuznets and Modern
economic growth fifty years later
Moshe Syrquin - 2005
Simon Kuznets was awarded the 1971
Nobel Prize in economics for his empirically founded
interpretation of economic growth, yet, two decades after his death it
is only in the guise of the
“Kuznets curve” that he may be found in the literature of growth or of
economic development. In
this paper I review Kuznets’ contribution to growth focusing
particularly on his analysis of the
costs and benefits of growth and the impossibility of conceptualizing
modern economic growth
without substantive structural shifts.
Kuznets maintained the impossibility of a purely economic theory of
growth. He considered the
more general theory as a worthwhile goal but a very remote one at the
time. The central problem
for Kuznets was to endogenize what economics mostly regards as givens:
technology, population,
tastes, and institutions.
In his studies of national income and growth Kuznets repeatedly
emphasized the problems of
scope, valuation, and the distinction between net and gross outputs.
The answers to these
questions depend on the purpose of economic activity which in turn
refers to the social values of
the place and time. The solutions, therefore, can never be absolute.
|
Turning points in
development thinking and practice
Louis Emmerij - 2005
In this article, I shall first
examine why and how the balance of development thinking and practice
changed
around 1980. This turning point coincided with a change of influence
(caused among others by the
industrial countries) at the level of strategic thinking from the UN to
the Bretton Woods Institutions.
Second, I shall look into the possibility of future turning points in
development thinking and practice. In
doing so, I shall describe, first, what could well become (and is
already becoming) a new and expanded
general concept of development, and second, the very opposite, namely
development not as a global but as
a regional and local strategy.
Having thus examined the future at the global, regional and national
levels of development thinking, the
article ends with reflections about the interests that lie behind the
ideas that help to explain why they get
implemented or not, why there are turning points or not.
|
3.2
POVERTY AND VULNERABILITY
|
Vulnerability,
unemployment and poverty: a new class of measures...
Kaushik Basu and Patrick Nolen - 2004
Measures of unemployment and poverty
have tended to focus solely on those currently
unemployed or below the poverty line. This approach has ignored the
members
of society that are vulnerable to becoming unemployed or falling into
poverty. Current
literature in this area has implicitly assumed that since someone who
is vulnerable
experiences pain from the chance of becoming unemployed or falling into
poverty, our
standard measures of unemployment and poverty do not accurately account
for this
pain. The implication is that vulnerability is a ‘bad’ and policies
should aim to reduce
the number of people who are vulnerable in a society. In this paper we
argue that, at
the macro level, vulnerability can be viewed as a ‘good’ because, with
unemployment
remaining constant, the presence of vulnerable people implies that
there must also exist
currently unemployed people who expect to find work in the near future.
And a
society where unemployment is more equitably shared is better than a
society where
the burden of unemployment is carried by only a few. Given this view of
vulnerability
we then suggest a class of measures that, unlike the standard
unemployment rate, account
for the amount of vulnerability that exists in a society. We show some
attractive
axioms that our measure satisfies, fully characterize our measure and
apply it to data
from the U.S. and South Africa.
|
Measuring
individual vulnerability
Cesar Calvo and Stefan Dercon - 2005
Standard poverty analysis makes
statements about deprivation after the veil of
uncertainty has been lifted. This implies that there is no meaningful
role for risk as
part of an assessment of potentially low states of well-being. In this
paper, we
introduce a concept of vulnerability, as a threat of poverty, with
downside risk at its
core. More specifically, we define a vulnerability measure as an
assessment of the
magnitude of the threat of poverty, measured ex-ante, before
uncertainty is resolved.
We describe the welfare-economic foundations for desirable properties
of a
vulnerability measure and assess to what extent some measures used in
empirical
work abide by them. We also present two families of measures that are
fully consistent
with our axiomatic approach.
|
Poverty
Persistence and Transitions in Uganda: A Combined Qualitative
and Quantitative Analysis
David Lawson, Andy McKay and John Okidi - December 2003
Uganda’s excellent record in reducing
the national incidence of monetary poverty
over the 1990s is widely known. Panel data though over this period
shows that this
net aggregate reduction was accompanied by substantial mobility into as
well as out
of poverty (Okidi and McKay, 2003). A majority of those that were poor
in 1992 had
escaped by 1999, but a substantial minority were left behind and many
others fell into
poverty over this period. Therefore, against the background of Uganda’s
impressive
macroeconomic performance over this decade, there was a significant
variation in
individual experiences of poverty movements, and it is important to
understand the
factors, many of which are individual or local, that contributed to
this.
This paper develops this understanding by combining qualitative and
quantitative
insights at the individual, household and community level.
|
Accounting
for Income Fluctuations in Distributional
Analysis: Theory and Evidence for Argentina
Guillemo Cruces - October 2006
This paper studies the impact of
income fluctuations on poverty, motivated
by the recurring economic crises that affect developing countries and
the incidence
of income fluctuations on household welfare. The paper presents a set
of
tools for empirical work based on theoretically sound extensions of the
existing
methodology for static distributional analysis. Results form
longitudinal
data for Argentina in the 1995-2002 period find that the large
fluctuations in
household income due to the repeated economic crises in the country in
this
period had a significant effect on household welfare.
|
3.3
FOREIGN AID
|
Can
foreign aid dampen external political shocks?
Lisa Chauvet - 2005
In this paper, an extended
econometric model of aid effectiveness is proposed. In growth
regressions – estimated by the application of the generalized method of
moments developed by Arellano and Bond (1991) – foreign aid and aid
interacted with various variables are introduced in order to capture
the conditions of aid effectiveness. Results suggest that aid
effectiveness depends :
(i) negatively on internal political instability ;
(ii) positively on vulnerability to trade shocks ; (iii) positively on
external political shocks, implying that aid can dampen the negative
impact of these shocks on economic growth.
This latter result suggests an extended notion of vulnerability, which
would affect positively aid effectiveness, and would be composed of
both economic and political shocks faced by developing countries.
|
A
Wider Approach to Aid Effectiveness: Correlated Impacts on Health,
Wealth, Fertility and Education
David Fielding, Mark McGillivray, and Sebastian Torres - February 2006
In this paper we discuss the results
of research into the impact of foreign aid on human
development. Rather than focussing on per capita income, as is common
in the existing
literature, we look at how aid impacts on a range of human development
indicators,
including measures, of health, education and fertility, and allow for
the fact that these
different dimensions of wellbeing are likely to interact with each
other. Overall, aid is
found to have a substantial positive impact on many development
outcomes.
|
IMF
Conditionality: Theory and Evidence
Axel Dreher - April 2006
This article analyzes whether and to
what extent reliance on conditionality is appropriate to guarantee the
revolving character of Fund resources. The paper presents theoretical
arguments in favour of conditionality, and those against the use of
conditions. It summarizes the track record of program implementation
and discusses the evidence of factors determining implementation.
Whether proponents or critics of conditionality can be supported by
existing data analysis is also investigated, as is the success of
conditionality in terms of outcomes. The final section draws policy
implications.
|
Aid,
Volatility and Growth Again: When Aid Volatility Matters and When It
Does Not
Lisa Chauvet and Patrick Guillaumont - 2008
In previous papers we have argued
that aid is likely to mitigate the negative effects of external shocks
on economic growth (i.e., aid is more effective in countries that are
more vulnerable to external shocks). Recently an important debate has
emerged about the possible negative effects of aid volatility itself.
However, the cushioning effect of aid may involve some volatility in
aid flows, which then is not necessarily negative for growth. In this
paper we examine to what extent the time profile of aid disbursements
may contribute to an increase or a decrease of aid effectiveness. We
first show that aid, even if volatile, is not clearly as procyclical as
often argued, and, even if procyclical, is not necessarily
destabilizing. We measure aid volatility by several methods and assess
procyclicality of aid with respect to exports, thus departing from
previous literature, which usually assesses procyclicality of aid with
respect to national income or fiscal receipts. The
stabilizing/destabilizing nature of aid is measured by the difference
in the volatility of exports and the volatility of the aid plus exports
flows. Then, in order to take into account the diversity of shocks to
which aid can respond, we consider the effect of aid on income
volatility and again find that aid is making growth more stable, while
its volatility reduces this effect. Finally, we find evidence through
growth regressions that the higher effectiveness of aid in vulnerable
countries is to a large extent due to its stabilizing effect.
|
3.4
DEVELOPMENT STRATEGIES
|
Patterns
of rent-extraction and deployment in developing countries. Implications
for Governance, Economic Policy
and Performance
Richard M. Auty - February 2006
Rents tend to be relatively high in
developing countries and also very fungible, so that
differences in the scale of the rent and in its distribution among
economic agents
profoundly affect the nature of the political state and the development
trajectory. This
paper identifies two basic trajectories to a high-income democracy
linked to the scale
and deployment of rents. Low-rent countries tend to engender
developmental political
states that competitively diversify the economy and sustain rapid per
capita GDP
(PCGDP) growth, which strengthens three key sanctions against
anti-social governance
(political accountability, social capital and the rule of law) to
achieve endogenous
democratization that is incremental. In contrast, rent-rich countries
are likely to
experience a slower and more erratic transition. This is because high
rents tend to
nurture non-developmental (predatory) political states whose deployment
of the rent
locks the economy into a staple trap, which carries a high risk of a
growth collapse. The
events presaging a growth collapse weaken sanctions against anti-social
governance.
However, a growth collapse may abruptly trigger democracy if exogenous
factors are
favourable, although such a change is likely to prove unstable and
prone to regression.
Very preliminary tests of the link between PCGDP growth and sanctions
against antisocial
governance suggest that social capital and law strengthen as predicted
by the
models for low-rent countries, but political accountability lags.
Rent-rich countries
exhibit the expected weaker link between PCGDP growth and
democratization, an
outcome consistent with a more erratic transition towards a high-income
democracy.
|
Credit
Co-operatives in Locally Financed Economic Development Using
Energy Efficiency as a Lever
Robert J. McIntyre - February 2006
In most transitional and many
developing countries institutions capable of supporting
economic development with localized saving-investment cycles have not
developed.
This crucial gap is in no way addressed by either country-level macro
programmes
dealing with ‘development finance’ or by donor-driven ‘micro credit’
schemes of
Grameen and other types operating at a lower (local) level. The latter
seldom evolve
into financial institutions able to sustain themselves on the basis of
local resources, do
not operate on a sufficient scale to trigger dynamic local-level
economic growth, and are
ultimately artificial manifestations of concessional or charitable aid.
The advantages of
credit co-operatives in mobilizing and financing local economic
development are
contrasted with the disadvantages of both conventional micro credit and
the most recent
neoliberal fashion of so-called ‘new wave financial institutions’. Both
precedent and the
structural logic suggest that this is a promising space for the
development of a localized
financial system based on credit co-operatives, which elsewhere have
overcome the
SME credit famine and stimulated local saving-investment cycles. Recent
Russian
developments are placed in the context of earlier experience in
structurally similar
conditions. These lessons apply to all other former Soviet Union
states, as well as other
countries.
|
Resources,
strategies, and investment climates as determinants of firm growth in
developing countries: A dynamic resource-based view of the firm
Keun Lee and Tilahun Temesgen - 2005
Using firm-level survey data sets
from a number of developing countries, this paper examines what make
firms grow successfully in developing countries. We use the investment
climate survey conducted by World Bank in eight developing countries
from different geographical locations covering a total of about 6,600
manufacturing firms.
As a basic theoretical framework, we rely on the resource-based theory
of the firm originally proposed by Penrose (1959) and its later
developments, such as the dynamic resource-based theory of the firm. In
Penrose theory, a firm is a bundle of resources (or capabilities) and
firm growth depends on what kinds and how much of the diverse resources
a firm has and how effectively it can utilize them for growth. The
findings of the paper are as follows.
First, in relatively low growth (capability) firms, growth is mainly
contributed by what can be termed as relatively basic resources such as
physical capital and human capital, whereas in high growth (capability)
firms, growth is, in a relative sense, more driven by higher level
resources such as managerial capital and R&D capital.
Second, not specific human capital but general human capital of workers
is found to have significant contribution to firm growth, whereas for
managers, specific knowledge rather than general knowledge is found to
be more important.
Third, difference between slow vs. high growth firms has more to with
the different effectiveness of relevant resources less with the
difference in the absolute amount of the resources.
Fourth, export orientation and conglomeration are the most important
strategies for firm growth, compared to networking with other local,
SOE or foreign firms.
|
Structural change and poverty reduction in
Brazil: the impact of Doha Round
Maurizio Bussolo, Jann Lay and Dominique van der Mensbrugghe - 2005
In their review of the relationship
between trade liberalization and poverty,
Winters, McCulloch and McKay (2004), conclude that trade liberalization
“may be one
of the most cost-effective anti-poverty policies available to
governments” although they
go on to note that it may not be the most powerful policy and its
effectiveness is likely to
vary substantially from case to case. In the medium to long run time
horizon, economies
adjust not only to trade policy reforms but also to many other changes,
including
technological progress, changes in the skill composition of the
population, and varying
consumption patterns. This chapter’s main objective is to assess the
role of trade
liberalization in poverty reduction over a time horizon during which
these other structural
trends are operating. In particular, we assess the poverty impact of a
Doha Round (and a
Full Liberalization) scenario on Brazil against a baseline scenario
that incorporates some
of the main features of medium run structural change but no changes in
trade policies.
|
3.5
CHINA
|
Development
Strategy, Viability, and Economic Institutions: The Case of China
Justin Yifu Lin, Mingxing Liu,
Shiyuan Pan, and Pengfei Zhang - May 2006
This paper explores the politically
determined development objectives and the intrinsic
logic of government intervention policies in east developed countries.
It is argued that the
distorted institutional structure in China and in many least developed
countries, after the
Second World War, can be largely explained by government adoption of
inappropriate
development strategies. Motivated by nation building, most
least-developed countries,
including the socialist countries, adopted a comparative advantage
defying strategy to
accelerate the growth of capital-intensive, advanced sectors in their
countries. In the paper
we also statistically measure the evolution of government development
strategies and the
economic institutions in China from 1950s to 1980s to show the
co-existence and coevolution
of government adoption of comparative advantage defying strategy and
the
trinity system.
|
State
ownership and corporate performance: a quantile analysis on China's
listed companies
Laixiang Sun, Tao Li and Liang Zou - November 2005
Assessing the effect of government
shareholding on corporate performance in the
context of China has been a hot topic. Documented results are mainly
empirical, and
the findings are diverse. In this paper we present a formal model that
establishes a
theoretical link between government shareholding and corporate
performance, where
firms receive private signals about their potential profitability and
make private effort.
Predicting a negative impact of government shareholding on corporate
performance,
our model further shows that this impact is more significant when the
firms’ perceived
profitability is high. Using a panel dataset of China’s listed
companies during 1994-
2000, we find that the estimations of conditional quantile regression
models are indeed
consistent with these predictions.
|
Economic opening and
industrial agglomeration in China
Zhao Chen, Yu Jin and Ming LuZhao - 2005
This paper explores the causes of
industrial agglomeration in China using the provincial panel data
during 1987-2001, focusing on the effects of economic opening. The
determinants of industrial
agglomeration are tested by controlling three types of factors, those
of economic policies, economic
geography and new economic geography, respectively. In summary, we
find: (1) Economic opening,
which is also related with geography and history encourages industrial
agglomeration; (2) Large
market size, effects of forward and backward linkage, high level of
urbanization, better infrastructure
and less involvement of local government tend to facilitate industrial
concentration; (3) Costal regions
have geographical advantage in attracting firms. These findings not
only support the new economic
geography theory from evidence within China, but also emphasize the
important role that policies like
economic opening might directly play in industrial agglomeration. The
most important policy
implication of this paper is that by quickening up the step of
integrating into world economy and
deregulating, even those less developed regions might accelerate
industrial agglomeration and thus
decrease regional disparity.
|
The
financial crises in East Asia. The cases of Japan, China, South Korea
and Southeast Asia
Beatriz Pont, Liu Lan, Fracisco García-Blanch, Clara García and Iliana
Olivié - 1998
|
4.1
GLOBALIZATION
|
Asymmetric
globalization: Global markets require good global politics
Nancy Birdsall - 2005
My remarks today are about
globalization, its asymmetries between rich and poor, and because of
its asymmetries, the need to rethink our global development
architecture. I will be talking mostly as an economist this afternoon,
but my real theme is that integration of the global economy is
outpacing the development of a healthy global polity. The globalization
of markets can and has brought mutual benefits to the rich and poor
alike. But it is only through better global politics that the values
and rules critical to a secure and just world will be realized, and it
is only then that the full benefits of a global market will be
available to all.
Put another way, good global politics is critical to the battle against
global poverty and unrealized human development, and to a more just and
fair as well as a more stable and prosperous global economy.
By globalization I mean the increasing integration of economies and
societies, not only in terms of goods and services and financial flows
but also of ideas, norms, information and peoples. In popular use,
however, the term globalization has come to mean the increasing
influence of global market capitalism or what is seen as the increasing
reach of corporate and financial interests at the global level.
|
The darker side of globalization - Ronald Findlay & Mats Lundahl |
The Impact of
Globalization on the World's Poor: Transmission Mechanisms
Machiko Nissanke and Erik Thorbecke - 2005
Over the recent decades, the world
economy has experienced not only a quantitative leap
in the volume and value of international trade and financial
transactions, but a qualitative
transformation in the way residents of different nation-states interact
with each other.
National economies are increasingly linked through international
markets for products
and factor markets, leading to increased cross-border flows of goods,
capital, labour, and
through flows of information, technology and management know-how. The
world
economy is becoming increasingly integrated.
This process of globalisation is one of the most critical developments
affecting the
evolution of national economies. Globalization offers participating
countries new
opportunities for accelerating growth and development but, at the same
time, it also
poses challenges to, and imposes constraints on policy makers in the
management of
national, regional and global economic systems. While the opportunities
offered by
globalization can be large, a question is often raised as to whether
the actual
distribution of gains is fair, in particular, whether the poor benefit
less than
proportionately from globalization – and could under some circumstances
actually be
hurt by it.
|
Globalization,
employment and poverty in Ghana
Ernest Aryeetey - 2005
One of the most significant
influences on the performance of the economy of Ghana
in the last two decades has been derived from the greater interaction
between it and
other economies. Thus, following economic reforms that focused
considerably on
opening the economy to greater and freer external trade, globalization
has been a
major aspect of the economy and society. But this influence has been
observed not
only in the area of external trade; it is seen also in terms of capital
flows, aid,
technology transfer, international migration, etc. All of these have
seen significant
expansion in the period of reforms, even if this has been on a scale
far smaller than in
South East Asia and the other faster growing developing economies.
|
4.2 A
NEW WORLD ECONOMIC ORDER
|
Appropriate
economic policies at different stages of development
Vladimir Popov and Victor Polterovitch
This paper summarizes theoretical
arguments and provides empirical evidence to support the
statement that rational economic policies depend qualitatively on two
factors – technological
and institutional level of development of a country. We concentrate on
the impact of three
policies to promote the catch up development – import tariffs, increase
of government
revenues/spending, and the speed of foreign exchange reserves
accumulation (“exchange rate
protectionism”). It is shown that the impact of these policies may be
positive or negative
dependening on a stage of development; in each case we find threshold
levels or critical
combinations of GDP per capita and/or an institutional quality
indicator.
A theoretical model demonstrates how tariff protection and accumulation
of reserves can
boost long term growth in the presence of externalities.
|
Real
exchange rate, monetary policy and employment: economic development...
Roberto Frenkel and Lance Taylor - 2006
The exchange rate affects the economy
through many channels and, consequently, has diverse
macroeconomic and development impacts. Five are analysed in this paper:
resource allocation,
economic development, fi nance, external balance and infl ation. The
use of the exchange rate as a
developmental tool in conjunction with its other uses (often in
coordination with monetary policy)
is at the focus of the discussion.
|
The Human Dimensions of
the Global Development Process in the Early
Part of the 21st Century.
Critical Trends and New Challenges
Mihály Simai - 2006
At the beginning of the twenty-first century there is a
rare coincidence of profound
transformations in a number of areas, in population dynamics, in human
settlements, in
science and technology, economics, social stratification, in the role
and functions of the
states and in the global power structure and in governance. The
systemic transformation
of the former socialist countries is an important component of the
ongoing changes
Political, economic, and social conditions vary immensely throughout
the world,
influenced by the size, natural endowments, development level, economic
structure,
political and institutional patterns, and competitiveness of the
countries. The new state
and non-state actors make the system of interests and values more
diverse. All these
have a major influence on the future of the global development process.
The paper
concludes that developing societies do not need old textbook models,
neoliberal or other
utopias. There is widespread demand for a new scientific thinking on
development, with
realistic and humanistic alternatives helping collaborative global and
national actions.
|
4.3 BEHAVIOURAL
APPROACHES |
Reforms and confidence
Pertti Haaparanta and Jukka Pirttila
We examine the choice of economic
reforms when policymakers have
present-biased preferences and can choose to discard information
(maintain confidence) to mitigate distortions from excess discounting.
The de-
cisions of policymakers and firms are shown to be interdependent.
Confident policymakers carry out welfare-improving reforms more often,
which
increases the probability that firms will invest in restructuring.
While policy makers in diferent countries can be equally irrational,
the consequences
of bounded rationality are less severe in economies with beneficial
initial
conditions. We also examine how present-biased preferences influence
the
choice between big bang versus gradualist reform strategies. Our
findings
help explain diferences in economic reform success in various countries.
|
Applying behavioral
economics to international development policy
C. Leigh Anderson and Kostas Stamoulis - 2006
Many national and international
economic development policies and programs are premised
on a traditional economic model of rationality that predicts how
individuals will respond to
changes in incentives. Empirical and experimental evidence, mostly from
Europe and the
U.S., is suggesting that there are a range of situations, especially
involving uncertainty and
costs and benefits spread over time, in which individuals make
decisions inconsistent with the
predictions of these models: individuals avail themselves more or less
than predicted in
health or credit programs, participate more or less than expected in
market opportunities,
under or over insure themselves, and make short run decisions that are
inconsistent with their
long run welfare.
Our primary research objective is to identify how development projects,
programs and
policies can be more effectively designed with a better understanding
of how individuals
make decisions in ways that systematically deviate from traditional
assumptions of rational
maximization.
|
Responding to economic
reform: the role of psychological factors
(PDF 475KB)
2005 - Renuka Chand & Sheetal K. Chand
Why do so many attempts at economic reform elicit weak responses? The
vast literature on this topic advances many economic and even political
explanations, but neglects psychological factors. This paper, with
Russia as a case study, considers some of the issues raised. Drawing on
the workhorse stressor-strain model from psychology, a link is
postulated to the standard economic reform paradigm via the concept of
psychological well being (PWB). Reforms can be stressful, impact
adversely on PWB, and result in counter-productive anti-social
behavior. The post-reform data from Russia is suggestive of both acute
stressors and widespread strains. To shed further light on inadequate
coping and buffering mechanisms, a cross-sectional sample of
individuals from St. Petersburg is examined. While the findings and
arguments are tentative, they point to the importance of adequate
psychological underpinnings in ensuring that responses to economic
reform are more successful.
|
Evolutionary psychology and development
economics
(PDF 306KB)
2005 - Wim A. Naudé
Contemporary development economics have provided much empirical
evidence to suggest that democracy and other institutions that promote
equity are good for growth and development. Why should this be the
case? In this paper it is argued that Evolutionary Psychology (EP) can
greatly enrich development economics, specifically in adding to our
understanding of the micro-foundations of the family unit and the
explanations of long-run economic growth and development. In this
paper, emphasis was placed on the evolutionary foundations of the
family unit, on the understanding of human co-operation, and how these
result in institutions, such as monogamous family units with positive
male parental investment, where a switch from preference for quantity
of children towards the quality of children leads to improved
technology and learning. Given that monogamy is more prevalent in a
more egalitarian society, institutions such as democracy and an
equality sensitive state may have biological roots. Human mate choices
influence co-operation, conflict and competition, and the existence and
nature of the family unit depend on such biologically determined
choices. In particular, the argument is made that human choice,
competition for mates, and the resulting sexual selection, lead to
different forms of pair-bonding such as monogamy or polygyny. Each of
these has different institutional repercussions, with different
development outcomes since the family / kinship environment in which
children grow up may have important implications for technology
adaptation, innovation and learning.
|
4.4
POVERTY
|
Has
world poverty really fallen during the 1990s?
Sanjay Reddy and Camelia Minoiu - 2007
We evaluate the claim that world
consumption poverty has fallen during the
1990s in light of alternative assumptions about the extent of initial
poverty and the rate of
subsequent poverty reduction in China, India, and the rest of the
developing world. We
assess the extent of poverty using two indicators: the aggregate
poverty headcount and
the poverty headcount ratio, and consider two international poverty
lines that are widely
used ($1.08/day and $2.15/day 1993 PPP). We find that under some of the
assumptions
considered, world poverty has risen. We conclude that, because of
uncertainties in
relation to the extent and trend of poverty in China, India, and the
rest of the developing
world, world poverty may or may not have increased. The extent of the
increase or
decrease in world poverty is critically dependent on the assumptions
made. Our
conclusions suggest the importance of improving the quality of global
poverty statistics.
|
Identifying
and understanding chronic poverty: beyond monetary measures
David Hulme and Andrew McKay - 2005
Despite the renewed commitment over
the past 15 years to poverty reduction as the core
objective of international development discourses and policies,
progress to this end remains
disappointing. This is particularly evident in the extent to which the
world is off track to
achieve most of the Millennium Development Goals, globally and in most
regions and
countries (UNDP, 2003; UN Statistics Division, 2004). This inadequate
progress raises
important questions about the policies and strategies (centred around
economic growth and
human development) that have been adopted to achieve poverty reduction,
as well as about
key international issues including aid, debt and trade.
|
Do
institutions matter in poverty reduction?. Prospects of Achieving the
MDG of Poverty
Reduction in Asia
Raghav Gaiha and Katsushi Imai - 2005
Millennium Development Goals (MDGs)
draw attention to several dimensions of deprivation
that afflict large sections of the population in the developing world,
and the imperative of
reducing them substantially by 2015. Although these goals are
inter-related, the most
fundamental one is to halve the proportion of the dollar poor between
1990-2015.
Achievement of this goal in Asia and the Pacific region- especially in
South Asia- is of
considerable importance as it accounted for 466 million of the 1.2
billion dollar poor in 1990.
The objective of this paper is to review progress in attaining the MDG
of poverty reduction,
assess prospects of achieving it by 2015, and identify priorities in
accelerating poverty
reduction in this region. A system of equations is specified and
estimated using 3SLS. In this
model, institutions are endogenous to historical and other exogenous
variables, openness is
endogenous to institutions, country size and a measure of physical
isolation, and income
inequality is endogenous to land inequality; income is posited to
depend on agricultural
income, openness, income inequality, institutions and regional
characteristics; the head-count
ratio of poverty is posited to depend on income, income inequality,
institutions and regional
characteristics. The estimated model and its variants are used to
simulate poverty outcomes in
two sub-regions of Asia and seven countries in this region in 2015
under different scenarios.
The results confirm the important role of agriculture in stimulating
overall growth;
institutions also have a significant effect on income; openness ceases
to have a significant
effect on income after its endogeneity to institutions and geographical
factors is taken into
account; income in turn lowers poverty while income inequality has a
positive effect; and
institutions have an effect on poverty but only through higher incomes.
The simulations
illustrate the need for growth acceleration –especially in South Asia-
reduction of income
inequality and institutional quality improvement. A somewhat striking
result is that even
modest institutional improvements have significant poverty reducing
effects through growth.
Factors that trigger such improvements are, however, not so obvious.
|
Identifying
asset poverty thresholds: new methods with an application to Pakistan
and Ethiopia
Feli Naschold
The degree of linearity in wealth
dynamics and the potential existence of asset thresholds
are at the core of two related microeconomic questions that are of
fundamental interest to
poverty reduction policies but about which we still know little. First,
do household asset
holdings converge unconditionally to a single long run equilibrium that
is high enough
for all poor households to escape poverty over time? Or do asset
thresholds exist below
the poverty line that households cannot overcome without assistance?
The latter would
make a good case for social policies that help lift the currently poor
household out of
poverty. A short term investment would be expected to yield long term
benefits. Second,
can short term shocks lead to long term destitution? If so, providing
insurance through
social safety nets would be a high return, long term investment, not
only protecting
current consumption but also future income streams of currently
non-poor households.
Answering these questions can help in designing more effective and
targeted poverty
reduction policies. However, the empirical literature on identifying
household welfare
dynamics and poverty thresholds is very small. The contribution of this
paper is
threefold. First, it compares existing techniques for identifying
poverty dynamics by
applying them to the same dataset. Second, it examines whether other
semi- and
nonparametric techniques may be more suitable for locating asset
poverty equilibria than
these existing techniques. Third, it contributes to the small emerging
empirical literature
on non-linear household welfare dynamics. It is the first study to use
a South Asian
dataset, and provides a comparison with Ethiopia.
|
DATABASE and models |
World
Income Inequality Database (WIID)
Susanna Sandstrom
In the UNU/WIDER World Income
Inequality Database (WIID) information on
income inequality for developed, developing, and transition countries
is stored.
WIID was initially compiled over 1997-1999 for the UNU/WIDER-UNDP
project "Rising Income Inequality and Poverty Reduction: Are They
Compatible?" directed by Giovanni Andrea Cornia, the former Director of
UNU/WIDER. As more observations were added to the database, WIDER
decided to make the database publicly available in order to facilitate
further
analysis and debate on inequality. This resulted in WIID version 1.0
which was
published in September 2000. The database was designed by Renato
Paniccia and
Sampsa Kiiski, the programming was done by Sampsa Kiiski, and the data
collected by Juha Honkkila, Renato Paniccia and Sampsa Kiiski.
The current update is part of the UNU/WIDER project "Global Trends in
Inequality and Poverty" directed by Tony Shorrocks, the Director of
UNU/WIDER and Guang Hua Wan, Senior Research Fellow at UNU/WIDER.
The revision and the update were made by Susanna Sandström and the
collection
of old source material by Taina Iduozee. Markus Jäntti, professor at
Åbo Akademi
Univerity and Senior Research Associate at UNU/WIDER was the advisor
for the
revision.
|
DARTS - a model for
the Distributional Analysis of the Russian Tax and Transfer System
models.wider.unu.edu DARTS enables you to act out
the role of the Russian Finance Minister. Using this on-line model you
can change various tax rates and state benefits including pension
levels and housing subsidies, and then track the effects on the people
of Russia: who pays the taxes, who gets the benefits, and who gains and
loses. DARTS does this by calculating the impact of the changes on a
representative sample of the Russian population taken from the Russia
Longitudinal Monitoring Survey.
|
NIEP
SOCIAL POLICY MODEL:
policy tool for fighting poverty in South Africa
Draft Final Report - Asghar Adelzadeh
Research Director and Senior Economic Modeller, NIEP - August 2001
Modelling is teamwork and the
microsimulation model developed by NIEP
and presented in this report is no exception. The construction of the
NIEP Social
Policy Model (NIEP-SPM) is the result of the contributions of a team of
six
researchers. The team members are Sam Bonti-Ankomah, Likezo Karn,
Piason
Mlambo, Matsuma Morunyane, Katerina Nicolaou and myself. Sam
Bonti-Ankomah
assisted in the development of the model’s pension module. Likezo Karn
reviewed
government documents for the identification of eligibility and
entitlement conditions
of more than ten government anti-poverty programmes. Piason Mlambo
prepared the
survey data that was used for the development of the model database. He
also assisted
in writing of a number of social security modules. Matsuma Morunyane
provided
assistance in the ageing of the data. Finally, Katerina Nicolaou
developed the tax,
value added tax, and unemployment insurance modules with little extra
help.
Constructed and applied microsimulation models
for ten African countries
: Botswana, Cameroon, Ghana, Mozambique, Nigeria, Namibia, South
Africa, Tanzania, Uganda, and Zambia
This website has been developed as
part of WIDER's project on Designing Africa's Poverty Strategies:
Creating the Capacity for Policy Simulation. It provides a
user-friendly access to ten African country economic models. You can
develop your own tax and transfer policy scenarios or conduct 'what if'
simulation analysis. Each model provides you with the poverty,
distribution, and budgetary impacts of your policy choices and compares
the simulation results with the current state or the base scenario. For
more information, you can contact Asghar Adelzadeh at adelzadeh@adrs-global.com.
|
5.1
WELLBEING AND HUMAN DEVELOPMENT
|
Health Improvements and Health Inequality during the Last 40
Years
Giovanni Andrea Cornia1 and Leonardo Menchini - 2006
This paper juxtaposes changes over the
last forty years in income growth and
distribution with the mortality changes recorded at the aggregate level
in about 170
countries and at the individual level in 26 countries with at least two
demographic and
health surveys covering the last twenty years. Over the 1980s and
1990s, the infant
mortality rate, under-5 mortality rate, and life expectancy at birth
mostly continued the
favourable trends that characterized the 1960s and 1970s. Yet,
especially in the 1990s,
the pace of health improvement was slower than that recorded during the
prior decades.
In addition, the distribution between countries of aggregate health
improvements
became markedly more skewed. These trends are in part explained by the
negative
changes recorded in sub-Saharan Africa and Eastern Europe, but are
robust to the
removal of the two regions from the sample. This tendency is observed
also at the
intraregional level, with the exception of Western Europe. Thirdly,
demographic and
health survey data for 26 developing countries point to a frequent
divergence over time in
the within-country distribution of gains in the infant mortality and
under-5 mortality
rates among children living in urban versus rural areas and belonging
to families part of
different quantiles of the asset distribution. The paper concludes by
underscoring the
similarities and linkages between changes in income inequality and
health inequality
and suggests some tentative explanations of these trends without,
however, formally
testing them.
|
Human
development: beyond the HDI
Gustav Ranis, Emma Samman and Frances Stewart
This paper explores ways of enlarging
the measurement and understanding of Human Development
(HD) beyond the relatively reductionist Human Development Index. From
the extensive literature
on well-being, we derived eleven categories of HD. Within each
category, we then identified a
potential set of indicators which were measurable and reflect
performance with respect to that
category. In order to reduce the number of indicators representing each
category, we included only
one for any set highly rank order correlated with each other, as well
as including indicators not
correlated with any other indicator in that category. Our aim was to
retain only indicators which are
broadly independent of each other.
|
Investing in Health for Economic Development: The Case of
Mexico
Nora Lustig - March 2006
Health is an asset with an intrinsic
value as well as an instrumental value. Good health
is a source of wellbeing and highly valued throughout the world. Health
is not only the
absence of illness, but capacity to develop a person’s potential.
Health is also an
important determinant of economic growth. Given the importance of
health, both as a
source of human welfare and a determinant of overall economic growth,
the Popular
Health Insurance (Seguro Popular) was first introduced in Mexico as a
pilot programme
by the federal government in 2001, becoming part of the formal
legislation in 2003.
This study looks at the current situation, and some of the early
findings and
improvements made so far with regard to public health coverage in
Mexico.
|
International
convergence or higher inequality and polarization of human development?
Evidence for 1975 to 2002
Farhad Noorbakhsh - February 2006
The concept of convergence is extended
to the human development index. Evidence of
weak absolute convergence is found over 1975-2002. The results are
robust and verified
by various conditional β-convergence models and also supported by the
evidence of
weak σ-convergence. Population weighted analyses provide support for
polarization in
the human development index amongst developing countries but a slight
reduction in
world inequality. The dynamics of regional analysis reveal a movement
of sub-Saharan
Africa towards the low band of human development with Asia and Latin
America
making progress. High immobility of the early part of the period is
followed by
considerable upward and downward mobility in the latter part indicating
a possible case
of the ‘twin peaks’ type of polarization.
|
Measuring
non-economic well-being achievement
Mark McGillivray - 2005
World Institute for Development
Economics Research, United Nations University, Helsinki
Income per capita and most widely reported, non- or non-exclusively
income based human well-being
indicators are highly correlated among countries. Yet many countries
exhibit higher achievement in the
latter than predicted by the former. The reverse is true for many other
countries. This paper commences
by extracting the inter-country variation in a composite of various
widely-reported, non-income-based
well-being indices not accounted for by variations in income pre
capita. This extraction is interpreted
inter alia as a measure of non-economic well-being. The paper then
looks at correlations between this
extraction and a number of new or less widely-used well-being measures,
in an attempt to find the
measure that best captures these achievements. A number of indicators
are examined, including measures
of poverty, inequality, health status, education status, gender bias,
empowerment, governance and
subjective well-being.
|
Human
Well-being: issues, concepts and measures
Mark McGillivray
National governments, civil society
organizations and international agencies
have for many years assembled and reported data on achieved human
wellbeing,
be it for individuals, families, regions or countries. Human well-being
achievement at the level of countries receives special attention. It is
now
commonplace for international agencies, such as the United Nations
Development
Programme (UNDP) and the World Bank, to publish annual reports
that rank countries according to various well-being or well-being
related
indicators.
|
5.2
TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT
|
What does evidence tell us about fragmentation and
outsourcing?
Ronald W. Jones, Henryk Kierzkowski and Chen Lurong
About thirty years ago international
trade economists uncovered a phenomenon that had
increasingly been permeating the international exchange of goods.
Thanks to the outstanding
work of Herbert Grubel and Peter Lloyd, overwhelming empirical evidence
has been
produced to demonstrate that a large part of international trade
consists of flows of goods
within the same industries.1 Two other stylized facts have emerged as
well: First, the
importance of intra-industry trade, as the new phenomenon came to be
known, increased over
time. Second, intra-industry exchanges have been particularly intensive
between developed
countries with similar per capita incomes and comparable factor
endowments.
New facts demanded new theory. Although Grubel and Lloyd offered some
penetrating
suggestions as to what could account for this novel type of trade, more
detailed theory
emerged. A fresh chapter in the theory of international trade opened,
with increasing returns
to scale and monopolistic competition gaining a permanent place.
|
Labour market
reform, trade liberalization, and political instability the world
around - Nauro Ferreira Campos |
Export
Diversification and Price Uncertainty in Developing Countries: A
Portfolio Theory Approach
Luisito Bertinellix, Andreas Heinen and Eric Stroblk - January 2009
Export Diversi¯cation and Price
Uncertainty in Developing
We evaluate the export diversification structure of developing
countries using a large
cross-country panel of detailed exporting activity and constructed
world market prices
in the context of modern portfolio theory. We found that there are
considerable welfare
gains from moving towards a more "optimal" export structure on the
mean-variance
efficient frontier, although the extent of this differs widely across
countries.
Our econometric analysis also shows while in general greater openness
has increased the expected earnings from exports, it has also resulted
in greater variability. Whether this has thus resulted in increases in
expected welfare depends crucially on the level of risk aversion of
countries.
|
International
trade and income distribution: reconsidering the evidence
Isabelle Bensidoun, Jean Sébastien and Aude Sztulman
Whether trade liberalization is
associated with narrowing or widening income disparities
within countries is still a matter of controversy. According to the
standard factor
proportions theory, openness should exert an equalizing effect in poor
countries and raise
income inequality in rich countries (if the skilled to unskilled
relative wage is to be
considered as a good proxy for income inequality). But this prediction
is not systematically
borne out by the data. While increased trade openness in several East
Asian economies
paralleled lowered inequalities, it is well documented that Latin
American countries
experienced a deterioration of their income distribution following
liberalization.
The publication in 1996 of a comprehensive data set on income
inequality paved the way
for more systematic empirical investigations than previously. However,
the studies failed to
deliver a convincing answer as to the link between openness and
inequality. Empirical
results are mixed: depending upon the sample, the econometric method or
the estimation
period, it is shown that openness has either no impact on inequality,
or has an equalizing
effect, or worsens the income distribution. In addition, the
conclusions do not fit the
underlying theoretical models.
This study reconsiders the evidence concerning the influence of
international trade on
income distribution, motivated by serious concerns about data
consistency, empirical
specification, as well as theoretical framework.
|
5.3
MIGRATION AND EMPLOYMENT
|
Migration
in the Development Studies Literature: Has It Come Out of Its
Marginality?
Arjan de Haan - February 2006
This paper explores the role migration
has played in development studies, and in
debates on economic growth and poverty. It argues that, despite a
recent surge of
interest in international migration and remittances, research on human
mobility
particularly for labour within poor countries does not have the place
it deserves, and that
it used to have in the classical development literature. Review of the
empirical literature
suggests that in fact much is known about the migration–development
relationship,
provided we are careful with definitions, and allow for
context-specificity to be a key
component of analyses. Against this richness of empirical detail, the
paper reviews
theoretical models of migration, finding significant differences in
understandings of
migration and its role in shaping wellbeing, but also
complementarities. This highlights
the importance of interdisciplinarity, and institutional understanding
of processes of
economic growth. In particular, it stresses that development economics
need to draw
more strongly on the insights by and approaches of non-economist social
sciences.
|
Labour Market Mobility of Low
Income Households
Arup Mitra - 2006
According to the “over-urbanisation”
thesis, migrants move into the urban areas
in search of jobs, and in the face of limited employment opportunities
in the high
productivity industrial sector, they continue to work in low
productivity activities. Urban
poverty here is a spillover of rural poverty. But why do migrants not
return to the rural
areas if they continue to be engaged in low productivity activities?
The reason could be that
the informal sector offers them a better source of livelihood compared
to rural avenues. This
argument prompts us to pose a number of questions from an empirical
standpoint. Based on
primary surveys of slum dwellers in Delhi, the author examines if
workers managed to
experience a change in their occupation, over time. Even when the broad
occupation
categories remain the same, does the nature of employment change and do
income levels
rise? If so, what role do networks play in helping them access better
paying jobs.
The findings tend to support upward mobility in a limited sense though.
|
Labor Markets in Low-Income
Countries:Distortions, Mobility and Migration
Mark R. Rosenzweig - March 1987
Prepared for the Handbook in Development Economics,
H. Chenery and T. N. Srinivasan, editors
Labor being by far the most abundant
resource in low-income countries, the
determination of the returns to labor plays a central role in models of
development. Any barriers to the reallocation of labor resources
accompanying
economic development are potentially critical impediments to further
income
growth. In the last 25 years, a great deal of knowledge has accumulated
about
labor-markets in low-income countries. Extreme views on labor market
processes
that had influenced thought for many years have been moderated by the
accumulation of empirical knowledge into a more eclectic and
empirically grounded
approach. This transformation has been influenced by both new
developments in microeconomic theory concerned with information and
risk
problems, critical realities of low-income countries, and the increased
availability of good data, which have disciplined theoretical exercises
and
helped weed out the merely clever models from those that inform.
|
Alternatives
to inflation targeting monetary policy for stable and egalitarian
growth: a brief research summary
Gerald Epstein - 2003
Many countries in the developing
world have adopted an approach to
monetary policy that focuses on maintaining a low level of inflation,
to the
exclusion of other important objectives such as employment generation,
increasing investment or reducing poverty, despite the widespread
evidence that moderate levels of inflation have few or no costs. Some
have
even adopted formal “inflation targeting”, an approach which commits
the
central bank to hitting a fairly rigid inflation target, often as low
as 2%.
However, this focus has led to slower economic growth and lower
employment growth, without succeeding in lowering inflation at a
smaller
economic cost than traditional methods of inflation fighting. Clearly,
it is
time to find an alternative to inflation targeting.
This paper presents the real targeting approach to monetary policy,
which
I argue is superior alternative to the costly and ineffective inflation
targeting approach. Under this real targeting approach, central banks
are
given a country appropriate target such as employment growth,
unemployment, real GDP or investment, usually subject to an inflation
constraint. Given these two targets – the real target and the
constraint – the
central bank will find multiple tools to reach these targets, designing
new
tools and rediscovering old tools such as asset based reserve
requirements
and other credit allocation techniques. The real targeting approach
might
also be complemented by other policies, such as capital management
techniques to deal with possible capital flight. The real targeting
approach
has the potential to make central bank policy more transparent, more
accountable, and more socially useful than most currently existing
central
bank structures.
|
5.4
AFRICA
|
Pro-poor
macro-micro policies for South Africa: economic modeling approach - Asghar
Adelzadeh |
From the African Development
Bank Group
Ways of Using the African Oil Boom for
Sustainable Development
Geerd Wurthmann - March 2006
Sub-Saharan-Africa is considered the
fastest-growing oil-producing region worldwide.
Production has risen by 36 percent in the past ten years (as against 16
percent
worldwide). Within 2005 alone, the revenue of the eight largest oil
countries of sub-
Saharan Africa will be about US$35 billion. The oil revenues can give
rise to a rentseeking
mentality. Political decision-makers may focus on distributing the
income on the
basis of private interests and not so much on putting it to use for
productive development
purposes. This paper reviews ways the African oil boom can be used for
sustainable
development of the continent.
|
Gender
Inequality and Growth: Evidence from
Sub-Saharan Africa and Arab Countries
Mina Baliamoune-Lutz and Mark McGillivray - September, 2007
This paper uses panel data from
African and Arab countries and Arellano-Bond estimations
to empirically assess the impact on growth of two primary indicators
that are associated
with MDG 3; namely the ratio of girls to boys in primary and secondary
enrolment, and the
ratio of 15-24 year-old literate females to males. Our findings
indicate that gender
inequalities in literacy have a statistically significant negative
effect that is robust to
changes in the specification. We show that higher gender inequality has
an even stronger
effect on income growth in Arab countries. In addition, in more open
economies, gender
inequality in literacy seems to have an additional effect, but this
effect is positive;
suggesting that trade-induced growth may be accompanied by greater
inequalities. The
results associated with the effects of gender inequality in primary and
secondary enrolment
are less robust.
|
Managing
Oil Rent for Poverty Reduction and Sustaining Development in Africa
(PDF 150KB) - Afeikhena
Jerome
|
Using Extractive Industries for
Sustainable Development
International Oil and Gas Resources
Management Seminar
Libreville, Gabon April 27-30, 2008
Summary Report - The World Bank Group
Natural resources are an important
and vital source of revenue
for many developing countries. Those resource-rich countries depend
on their revenues to drive growth. The World Bank recently launched
a new initiative to help developing countries manage and transform
this new wealth into long-term economic growth and to spread the
benefits more fairly among their people.
The so-called Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative Plus
Plus (EITI++) was designed to help countries develop their capacity
to handle the boom in commodity prices and channel the growing
revenues into reducing poverty, hunger, malnutrition, illiteracy, and
disease. The success of the program and its effectiveness depends on
the countries themselves, which must take responsibility for managing
the resources and setting the targets for positive results. The
initiative
aims to improve the awarding of petroleum contracts, monitoring
operations, and the collection of taxes and royalties. It will
also help countries build capacity to make economic decisions on
resource extraction, managing price volatility, and investing revenues
effectively for national development.
|
EU-ACP Economic Partnership Agreements:
Implication for Trade and Development in West Africa (PDF 84KB) - Adeola F. Adenikinju and Olumuyiwa
B. Alaba |
6.1
INTERNATIONAL FINANCE
|
International
Finance and the developing world: the next twenty years
Tony Addison - 2006
Much has changed in international
finance in the twenty years since UNU-WIDER was
founded. This paper identifies five broad contours of what we might
expect in the next
twenty years: the flow of capital from ageing societies to the more
youthful economies of
the South; the growth in the financial services industry in emerging
economies and the
consequences for their capital flows; the current strength in emerging
market debt, and
whether this represents a change in fundamentals or merely the effect
of low global
interest rates; the impact of globalization in goods markets in
lowering inflation
expectations, and therefore global bond yields; and the implications of
the adjustment in
global imbalances between Asia (in particular China) and the United
States for emerging
bond markets as a whole. The paper ends by noting the paradox that
today we see ever
larger amounts of capital flowing across the globe in search of
superior investment
returns, and yet the financing needs of the poorer countries are still
largely unmet.
|
International
risk tolerance, capital market failure and capital flows to emerging
markets
Valpy Fitzgerald - April 2006
The level, tenor and instability of
capital flows from global financial markets towards
developing countries are a major source of concern for macroeconomic
managers, while
their causes remain largely unexplained by economic theory. Country
‘fundamentals’
(such as economic growth, monetary stability and institutional
capacity) as sources of
default risk have been the main focus of economic research and policy
prescriptions.
However, recent empirical research on the determinants of capital flows
and the roots of
market failure indicate that much of the explanation lies in the nature
of the home (that
is, the developed country) demand for emerging market assets. In this
paper, the
microeconomic roots of home bias and demand instability are explained
in terms of
investor risk perception and credit rationing, exacerbated by traders’
behaviour. The
consequences for host country macroeconomic balances and income
distribution
of varying investor risk tolerance are then demonstrated. Although the
net impact also
depends upon the host policy response, this transmission mechanism
means that host
‘fundamentals’ are themselves strongly affected by capital flows and
thus cannot be
considered as to be independent of home asset demand. The paper
concludes by
examining the implications of these findings for the future of
development economics in
general and for policy response in particular.
|
Capital
flows and macroeconomic policy in emerging economies
Manuel Rodolfo Agosin - 2006
As a consequence of the foreign
capital surge experienced by many developing countries,
since the early 1990s international economists and policy makers have
been debating
whether foreign capital flows should be the object of specific policy.
The debate has
crystallized into two opposite stances. On the one hand, some claim
that capital flows are
not only primarily exogenous to the recipient countries but also
destabilizing (see, for
example, Agosin and Ffrench-Davis, 1996 and 2001). This view recommends
that
economic authorities should design and implement policies to dampen the
impact of
capital flows on domestic macroeconomic variables. The opposing view
departs from the
assumption that capital flows largely respond to domestic variables,
whether they are
long term (i.e., affecting the country’s risk premium) or related to
short-term demand
management. This approach argues that there is no need to worry
explicitly about capital
flows and that policy makers should concentrate exclusively on
improving domestic
policies.
|
6.2
PRO-POOR POLICIES
|
On
assessing pro-poorness of government programmes: international
comparisons
Nanak Kakwani and Hyun H. Son - May 2006
Nanak Kakwani and Son*
This paper suggests how the targeting efficiency of government
programmes may be
better assessed. Using the ‘pro-poor policy’ (PPP) index developed by
authors, the study
investigates the pro-poorness of not only government programmes geared
to the poorest
segment of the population, but also basic service delivery in
education, health and
infrastructure. This paper also shows that the targeting efficiency for
a particular
socioeconomic group should be judged on the basis of a ‘total-group PPP
index’, to
capture the impact of operating a programme within the group. Using
micro-unit data
from household surveys, the paper presents a comparative analysis for
Thailand, Russia,
Vietnam and 15 African countries.
|
Linkages
between Pro-Poor Growth,
Social Programmes and Labour
Market: The Recent Brazilian
Experience
Nanak Kakwani, Marcelo Neri,
and Hyun H. Son - April 2009
This paper analyses the relationship
between growth patterns, poverty, and inequality in Brazil
during its globalization process, focusing on the role played by the
labour market and social
programmes. Methodologically, the paper makes two contributions to the
literature. One is the
proposal of a new measure of pro-poor growth, which links growth rates
in mean income and in
income inequality. The other contribution is a decomposition
methodology that explores linkages
between three dimensions: growth patterns, labour market performances,
and social policies. The
proposed methodologies are then applied to the Brazilian National
Household Survey covering the
period 1995–2004.
|
Exchange
rate regimes and pro-poor growth Rolf Maier - 2005
This paper extends the ongoing
discussion on optimal exchange rate regimes to the issue of pro-poor
growth. To analyze empirically the poverty effects of exchange rate
regimes, we estimate the distribution
effects of different exchange rate arrangements on the poorest 20 and
20 to 40 percent. In addition, we
test the total effect, i.e. the distribution and growth effect, to
capture potential trade-offs between poverty
effects through overall economic growth and distribution.
To analyze this question, we collect an irregular and unbalanced panel
of time-series cross-country data
on the first and second quintile share from 76 countries and use two
recently proposed de facto exchange
rate regime classifications, Levy-Yeyati/Sturzenegger (2002) and
Reinhart/Rogoff (2003). To cover
econometric issues, cross-country variation and dynamic aspects of
within-country changes of the income
of the poor, we apply two econometric specifications, a growth equation
and a system GMM estimation.
We estimate the poverty effects of different exchange rate regimes for
all countries and, separately,
developing and industrial countries due to considerable differences in
economic structure, access to
international capital markets and soundness of domestic financial
systems.
|
Poverty
Accounting by Factor Components
With an Empirical Illustration Using Chinese Data
Guanghua Wan - June 2006
The purpose of this paper is to develop two poverty
decomposition frameworks and to
illustrate their applicability. A given level of poverty is broadly
decomposed into an
overall inequality component and an overall endowment component in
terms of income
or consumption determinants or input factors. These components are
further
decomposed into finer components associated with individual inputs.
Also, a change in
poverty is decomposed into components attributable to the growth and
redistributions of
factor inputs. An empirical illustration using Chinese data highlights
the importance of
factor redistributions in determining poverty levels and poverty
changes in rural China.
|
6.3
TECHNOLOGY AND DEVELOPMENT
|
The
technology clubs: The distribution of knowledge across nations
Fulvio Castellacci and Daniele Archibugi - October 2008
The convergence clubs literature in
applied growth theory suggests that countries that
differ in terms of structural characteristics and initial conditions
tend to experience diverging
growth performances. What is the role of technological knowledge for
the formation
of clubs? The paper investigates this unexplored question by carrying
out an empirical
study of the cross-country distribution of knowledge in a large sample
of developed and
developing economies in the 1990s. The results indicate the existence
of three technology
clubs characterized by markedly different levels of development. The
clubs also differ with
respect to the dynamics of their capabilities over the decade, as the
most advanced group
and the intermediate one are found to be much more dynamic than the
large cluster of less
developed economies.
|
Transforming
Digital Divide into Digital Dividend:South-South Cooperation in
Information-Communication
Technologies
Joseph K. Joseph - 2005
Countries in the South are making
widespread use of information-communication
technologies (ICTs) adopted from the North, but have largely neglected
their domestic
production. To reduce this technological dependence, countries should
integrate both
production and use and draw on the substantial ICT capabilities
existing in the
South through bilateral, regional and inter-regional cooperation. Such
broad pooling of
resources would achieve economies of scale and minimize risks,
according to K.J. Joseph,
Professor at the Centre for Development Studies, Trivandrum, Kerala,
India.
He is also Visiting Senior Fellow, Research and Information System
(RIS)
for Non-Aligned and Other Developing Countries, New Delhi.
|
Telecommunications
infrastructure and economic growth: evidence from developing countries
Sridhar K. S. and Sridhar V. - 2007
In this study, we investigate
empirically the relationship between telephone penetration and economic
growth, using data for developing countries. Using 3SLS, we estimate a
system of equations that endogenizes economic growth and telecom
penetration. We find that the traditional economic factors explain
demand for mainline and mobile phones, even in developing countries. We
find positive impacts of mobile and landline phones on national output,
when we control for the effects of capital and labor. We discuss the
associated policy implications related to improvement of telecom
penetration in developing countries.
|
Innovations,
high-tech trade and industrial development: Theory, Evidence and Policy
Lakhwinder Singh - March 2006
Innovations spur science-based trade
and industrial development in a fast changing pace
of globalization. Knowledge accumulation and diffusion have been
increasingly
recognised as fundamental factors that play an important role in
long-run economic
growth. This paper focuses on the long-term innovation strategy of
industrial and
technological development in developing countries. Growth theory,
empirical evidence
and several indicators of innovation have been pressed into service to
draw important
lessons from historical experience of the developed and newly
industrializing countries
for the industrial development of the developing economies. Technology
development
and public technology policy experience of the East Asian countries
have been
examined to reinvent the role of public technology policy that can be
adopted to develop
national innovation system to nurture and build innovative capabilities
in the developing
economies in the dynamic global economy.
|
6.4
INFORMAL SECTOR
|
The
Informal Economy
Published by Swedish International Development Cooperation Agency, 2004
Department for Infrastructure and Economic Cooperation
Author: Kristina Flodman Becker
During 2002, Sida initiated the
development of a private sector policy.
According to the instructions for the policy development, Sida should
among others highlight issues of relevance to the informal economy
in its partner countries. In addition, the Private Sector Development
working group is planning to conduct a seminar on the informal
economy in developing countries. Within the framework of the
current Private Sector Policy Development and in view of the future
seminar, Sida has commissioned a consultant, Ms Kristina Flodman
Becker, to provide a background for further discussions within Sida
related to the informal economy in Sida’s partner countries. The
consultant has received invaluable assistance from Ms Annika Nilsson
at Sida who has recently returned from Bolivia where she was appointed
as an Associate Bilateral Expert at the National Chamber of
Industries.
|
Labor dynamics and the
informal economy
Yusufchan Masatlioglu and Jamele Rigolini
|
Information sharing among competing
microfinancing providers (PDF 207KB) - Sanjay
Jain & Ghazala Mansuri |
Microfinance and the achievemnt of the
Millennium Development Goals: a case for subsidies (PDF 148KB) - Bernd Balkenhol |
6.5
RURAL DEVELOPMENT
|
Three
decades of rural development projects in Asia, Latin America, and
Africa...Learning From Successes and Failures
Annelies Zoomers - March 2006
This article aims to contribute to the
discussion about how to make development
interventions more effective by analyzing the factors contributing to
the success or
failure of rural development projects. We made an aggregate level
analysis of 46
projects in the field of agricultural research (AR), water management
(WM), natural
resource management (NRM), and integrated rural development (IRD),
financed by the
Netherlands’ Directorate-General for International Cooperation (DGIS)
and carried out
between 1975-2005 in Asia, Africa and Latin America. Making a
distinction between
the successful projects and failures, we showed the possibilities and
limitations
of evaluating projects on the basis of the official criteria
(relevance, efficiency,
effectiveness, sustainability and impact and/or using criteria such as
poverty, gender,
institutional development, governance and environment). We learned that
project
performance very much depends on whether interventions ‘keep track’
with local
priorities and trends. This is much more important than ‘measuring
output’ (are results
in line with the project goal?) which is wrongly presented as a
priority in monitoring
and evaluation practices.
|
Rainfall
and Africa's growth tragedy
Salvador Barrios, Luisito Bertinelli and Eric Strobl
We examine the role of the general
decline in rainfall in sub-Saharan African nations in their poor growth
performance relative to other developing countries. To do so we use a
new cross-country panel climatic data set in an economic growth
framework. Our results show that rainfall has been a significant
determinant of poor economic growth for Africa, but not for other
developing countries. Depending on the benchmark measure of potential
rainfall, we estimate that the direct impact under the scenario of no
decline in rainfall would have resulted in a reduction of between
around 9 and 23 per cent (i.e.,. between 374 and 787 dollars per
capita) of today’s gap in African GDP per capita relative to the rest
of the developing world.
*
|
Agrarian
relations among village households - V. K. Ramachandran |
Non-agricultural
land use and land reform: theory and evidence from Brazil
Juliano J. Assunçao - 2005
This paper examines the effect of
nonagricultural land use on agrarian organization
and land reform, providing a simple model to determine its policy
implications and
some evidence on its importance. It is argued that, if land-rental
market is imperfect,
there is a role for redistributive land policies and the following
implications hold: (i)
land reform is more probable to enhance efficiency in a low-wage
economy; (ii) such
policies should aim small farmers instead of landless people, obtaining
land from
large landholders. Empirical evidence suggests this is a relevant issue
in Brazil,
specially during periods of high macroeconomic instability.
|
7.1
ACHIEVING THE MDGs
|
Building
absoptive capacity to meet the MDGs
François Bourguignon and Mark Sundberg - May 2006
The ability of low-income countries to productively
absorb large amounts of external
assistance is a central issue for efforts to scale-up aid. This paper
examines absorptive
capacity in the context of MDG-based development programmes in
low-income countries.
It first defines absorptive capacity, and proposes a framework for
measuring it. Applying a
dynamic computable general equilibrium model to link the macro
framework to sector
results, the paper simulates MDG scenarios for Ethiopia and examines
the role of
infrastructure, skilled labour, macroeconomic, and other constraints on
absorptive capacity.
The main policy conclusions are that careful sequencing of public
investment across
sectors is key to minimizing the costs of reaching the MDGs; the macro
impact of large aid
flows on the tradeables sector can potentially be serious in the short
run; large-scale
frontloading of aid disbursements can be costly as it pushes against
absorptive constraints;
and that improvement of governance and institutional structures can
significantly reduce
the cost of achieving the MDGs.
|
Achieving
the Millennium Development Goals: what is wrong with existing
analytical models?
Sanjay Reddy and Antoine Heuty - 2006
Th is study critically evaluates
analytical models presently used to estimate the cost of achieving the
Millennium Development Goals (MDGs) from sources including the UN
Millennium Project, the
UN Development Programme, the World Bank and the Zedillo Commission.
Effective strategic
choices for achieving the MDGs must be based on sound assessments of
the costs and benefits of
alternative policies. However, the existing approaches are unreliable.
They derive from implausible
and restrictive assumptions, depend on poor quality data, and are
undermined by the presence of
large uncertainties concerning the future. An alternative and less
technocratic approach to planning
is required.
|
Health,
wealth, fertility, education and inequality
David Fielding and Sebastian Torres - 2005
This paper uses a new cross-country
dataset to estimate the strength of the links
between different dimensions of social and economic development,
including
indicators of health, fertility and education as well as material
wellbeing. The
paper differs from previous studies in employing data for different
income
groups in each country in order to provide direct evidence on factors
driving
inequality, and in using a unique measure of material wellbeing that
does not
rely on PPP comparisons.
|
7.2
GROWTH
|
Manufacturing,
services, jobless growth and the informal economy: Will services be the
new engine of Indian economic growth?
Partha Dasgupta and Ajit Singh - 2005
This paper revisits the role of
manufacturing and services in economic
development in the light of the following new facts:
(a) a faster growth of
services than that of manufacturing in many developing countries (DCs).
(b)
The emergence of “de-industrialisation” in several DCs at low levels of
per
capita income.
(c) Jobless growth in the formal sector even in fast growing
countries such as India and
(d) a large expansion of the informal sector in both
fast growing and slow growing DCs.
Although the paper examines these
phenomena in the specific case of the Indian economy, the analysis has
much
wider application, both for economic policy and for theories of growth
and
structural change.
|
Methods
of privatization and economic growth in transition economies
John Bennet, Saul Estrin, James Maw and Giovanni Urga
We develop an analytical framework to
investigate the impact of differences in
privatisation methods, private sector and capital market on economic
growth in
transition economies. Using dynamic panel data methods, a growth
equation is
estimated. Growth is found to be positively associated with capital
market
development. However only mass privatisation is found to have a
significant positive
effect on growth. The explanations we suggest relate to the
underdeveloped capital
market in transition economies. If the wealth distribution inherited
from communism
is ‘wrong,’ the matching of owners to firms under full privatisation
will be inefficient.
This finding has important implications for privatisation methods in
less developed
countries.
|
Decomposing
growth: do low-income and HIPCs differ from high-income countries?
Growth, Technological Catch-up,
Technological Change and Human
and Physical Capital Deepening
Pertti Haaparanta and Heli Virta - 2006
This paper studies the distribution of
output per worker between the years 1980 and
2000 in different country groups. The study uses data envelopment
analysis (DEA) to
decompose the changes in the distribution of labour productivity into
changes in
productive efficiency, changes in best practice technology,
accumulation of physical
capital, and accumulation of human capital. The study focuses on
low-income countries
and within them on highly indebted poor countries (HIPCs), which has
not been
possible in earlier studies.
|
Gender
and growth in sub Saharan Africa: evidence and issues
Mark Blackden, Sudharshan Canagarajah, Stephan Klasen and David Lawson
The study suggests that gender
inequality acts as a significant constraint to growth in
sub-Saharan Africa, and that removing gender-based barriers to growth
will make a
substantial contribution to realizing Africa’s economic potential. In
particular we
highlight gender gaps in education, related high fertility levels,
gender gaps in formal
sector employment, and gender gaps in access to assets and inputs in
agricultural
production as particular barriers reducing the ability of women to
contribute to
economic growth. By identifying some of the key factors that determine
the ways in
which men and women contribute to, and benefit (or lose) from, growth
in Africa,
we argue that looking at such issues through a gender lens is an
essential step in
identifying how policy can be shaped in a way that is explicitly
gender-inclusive and
beneficial to growth and the poor. We also argue that in some
dimensions and channels
of the gender-growth nexus, the evidence is only suggestive and needs
further detailed
research and analysis. Investigations of the linkage between gender
inequality and
growth should therefore be a priority for development economics
research in coming
years.
|
7.3
COUNTRY STRATEGIES
|
- Development Strategy,
Viability, and Economic Institutions: The Case of China
Justin Yifu Lin, Mingxing Liu,
Shiyuan Pan, and Pengfei Zhang - May 2006
This paper explores the
politically determined development objectives and the intrinsic
logic of government intervention policies in east developed countries.
It is argued that the
distorted institutional structure in China and in many least developed
countries, after the
Second World War, can be largely explained by government adoption of
inappropriate
development strategies. Motivated by nation building, most
least-developed countries,
including the socialist countries, adopted a comparative advantage
defying strategy to
accelerate the growth of capital-intensive, advanced sectors in their
countries. In the paper
we also statistically measure the evolution of government development
strategies and the
economic institutions in China from 1950s to 1980s to show the
co-existence and coevolution
of government adoption of comparative advantage defying strategy and
the
trinity system.
Development in Chile
1990-2005: Lessons from a Positive Experience
Álvaro García Hurtado - February 2006
Chile, in the last 15 years, has
shown remarkable results in terms of growth, poverty
reduction and democratic governance. This paper reviews the structural
changes that
were behind these positive outcomes, as well as the pending challenges
for Chile’s
development. Also shows that Chile did better in terms of growth than
social integration
and that this is related to the weak representation and participation
of a wide majority in
the national debate and decision making process. It also draws
conclusions valid for
other Latin American countries’ development.
|
Growth
and Equity in Finland
Markus Jantti, Juho Saari and Juhana Vartiainen - July 2006
This paper reviews Finnish economic
history during the ‘long’ twentieth century with a
special emphasis on policies for equity and growth. We argue that
Finland developed
from a poor, vulnerable, and conflict-prone country to a modern economy
in part
through policies geared at both growth and equity, such as land reform
and compulsory
schooling. The state participated in economic activity both indirectly
and directly in the
post-war period, implementing many social policy reforms that
facilitated the
functioning of the labour market and led to greater equity. Centralised
collective
bargaining was just one of the many means through which central
government
intervened in the economy. Both the long-run growth record and the
equality of
different kinds of economic outcomes are fairly positive. This suggests
that facilitating
economic growth through such policies that further more equitable
outcomes may at
least in the case of Finland have met with some success.
Keywords:
|
RP2006/12
Guillermo Rozenwurcel:
Why
Have All Development Strategies Failed in Latin America?
After the Great Depression and
throughout the rest of the twentieth century, Latin
American countries basically approached economic development following
two
successive and quite opposed strategies. The first one was import
substitution
industrialization. The second was the so-called Washington Consensus
approach. While
the two views were founded on quite opposite premises, neither the
import substitution
industrialization nor the Washington Consensus managed to deliver
sustained economic
development to Latin American countries. Two domestic elements are
crucial to
understand this outcome. One is the failure of the state. The second is
the inability to
achieve mature integration into the world economy.
|
7.4
CULTURAL AND SOCIAL CAPITAL
|
Ethnic
Structure and Cultural Diversity around the World: A Cross-National
Data Set on Ethnic Groups
James D. Fearon - January 2003
Development economists have recently
focused on ethnic diversity, or “fractionalization,” as a possible
cause of corruption, political instability, and poor economic
performance. Political scientists have argued
for years over possible links between ethnic diversity (or structure)
and civil violence, democratic stability,
and party systems. For its empirical evaluation in a cross-national
setting, all such research requires
data on ethnic groups across countries. This paper tries to do a better
job of conceptually grounding,
operationalizing, and constructing a list of ethnic groups across
countries than is currently available.
After addressing conceptual and practical problems involved in
enumerating “ethnic groups,” I present
a list of 820 ethnic groups in 160 countries that made up at least 1%
of country population in the
early 1990s. I compare a measure of ethnic fractionalization based on
this list with the commonly used
fractionalization measure based on the Atlas Narodov Mira (1964).
Finally, I construct an index of cultural
fractionalization that uses the structural distance between languages
as a proxy for the cultural distance
between groups in a country. This latter measure may be more
appropriate when testing hypotheses
that assume that ethnic groups “matter” because they have diverse
preferences and cultural differences
that pose obstacles to cooperation.
|
The
future of social capital in development economics research
Stephen Knowles - 2005
Social capital is generally
interpreted as the degree of trust, co-operative norms and networks
and associations within a society. Economists have become increasingly
interested in social
capital, following the seminal work of Coleman (1988) and Putnam
(1993). Since the
publication of these studies a vast quantity of research on social
capital has been published by
economists, as well as researchers from other academic disciplines.
This paper critiques a
selection of the literature on social capital, in terms of its
definition, measurement and effects.
In terms of definitions, it is argued that social capital is a very
similar concept to informal
institutions, as defined by North (1990). It is argued that parallels
can be drawn between the
literature on social capital, and the empirical literature on the role
of institutions as a deep
determinant of economic development. Turning to the future of social
capital research, it is
argued that valuable insights can be gleaned from the institutions
literature.
|
The inequality trap
Eric Uslaner - 2005
Successful (or “well-ordered”)
democracies are marked by high levels of trust in other
people and in government, low levels of economic inequality, and
honesty and fairness in the
public sphere. Trust in people, as the literature on social capital has
shown, is essential for
forming bonds among diverse groups in society (see Uslaner, 2002).
Trust in government is
essential for political stability and compliance with the law.
Corruption robs the economy of
funds and leads to less faith in government (perhaps also to less faith
in fellow citizens) and thus
lower compliance with the law. And institutions seen as biased (unfair)
cannot secure compliance
and may exacerbate inequalities in society.
|
Papers
related to the conference
-
|
|
|