World Bank, 1984, "Pioneers in Development" (Public Disclosure Authorized -
June 1984)
The "Pioneers in Development" are those whose
articles, reports, and books came
to dominate thinking about economic
development in the late 1940s and 1950s.
They shaped the subject by introducing concepts,deducing
principles, and modeling the process of
development This book recaptures the spirit and the economic thought of that
pioneering period.
The pioneers listed on the front of the jacket were asked
to reassess the main themes of their early work and
to reconsider their assumptions, concepts, and policy
prescriptions in relation to the way the course of
development has proceeded since their pioneering days.
Their individual chapters now recall the intellectual excitement, expectations,
and activism of that unique period.
Commentary is provided by economists
of the succeeding generation, who reappraise their elder's ideas with the
benefit of hindsight.
Not only do the chapters by the pioneers display autobiographical
charm, but, taken as a set, they also offer
an unusual opportunity for a retrospective view of
what has happened to development economics. And
the retrospective view naturally has implications for
assessing the present and looking to the future. What
are the strands of continuity in development?
What are the recurrent issues? What
are the unsettled questions?
An introductory historical chapter by Gerald M. Meier
sets the stage, outlining some of the intellectual trends
and institutional features that shaped the political
and economic environment of the formative period for the pioneers. The final
survey chapter by Paul P. Streeten
synthesizes various issues in developmentthought
and points toward the resolution of unsettled questions in the subject.
Contents Foreword A. W. Clausen
v Preface Gerald M. Meier ix Introduction
The Formative Period Gerald M. Meier
THE SUBJECT MATTER OF DEVELOPMENT ECONOMICS is at once among the
oldest and newest branches of economics. Beginning with Adam Smith's
Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, classical
economists sought to discover the sources of economic progress and to
analyze the long-run process of economic change. As Nobel laureate
Arthur Lewis reminds us, what Smith called "the natural progress of
opulence" is what we today call "development economics." During a long
interim, however, the marginalist analysis of neoclassical economists introduced
a static frame of thinking and shifted interests to the narrower
problems of resource allocation and the theory of exchange. And the
depressed conditions of the interwar period gave rise to the Keynesian
analysis of short-period business cycles and the possible threat of secular
stagnation in mature capitalist nations. A return to growth and development
as the grand theme of economics did not come until after the Second
World War. The late 1940s and 1950s then became in many respects the
pioneering period for the "new" development economics that focused on
the development problems of Asian, African, and Latin American
countries.'
Pioneers:
Lord Bauer, Remembrance of Studies Past:
Retracing First Steps
THE FOLLOWING is a reasonable summary of the principal components to
the burgeoning development literature of the early postwar years.
External trade is at best ineffective for the economic advance of less
developed countries (LDCS), and more often it is damaging. Instead, the
advance of LDcs depends on ample supplies of capital to provide for
infrastructure, for the rapid growth of manufacturing industry, and for the
modernization of their economies and societies. The capital required
cannot be generated in the LDCS themselves because of the inflexible and
inexorable constraint of low incomes (the vicious circle of poverty and
stagnation), reinforced by the international demonstration effect, and by
the lack of privately profitable investment opportunities in poor countries
with their inherently limited local markets. General backwardness, economic
unresponsiveness, and lack of enterprise are well-nigh universal
within the less developed world. Therefore, if significant economic advance
is to be achieved, governments have an indispensable as well as a
comprehensive role in carrying through the critical and large-scale changes
necessary to break down the formidable obstacles to growth and to initiate
and sustain the growth process.
Comment Michael Lipton Comment T. N.
Srinivasan
Colin Clark: Development Economics: The Early Years
My first publication on British national product, covering the years
1924-31, appeared in 1932; a more thorough study, which appeared in
1937, also made provisional attempts at long-period historical comparisons
and at quarterly information for recent periods. This publication,
however, caused a break in the international studies which I had already
commenced and which were to conclude in the publication of The Conditions
of Economic Progress in 1940.
At that time, and for many years afterwards, it was believed that the key
factor in economic growth was the accumulation of capital. As early as
1937 I began profoundly to question this doctrine, in the concluding
paragraphs of the book National Income and Outlay. We know now that
such an accumulation is a necessary but not a sufficient condition for
economic progress, an important logical distinction. On this more below.
Comment Graham Pyatt
Albert 0. Hirschman: A Dissenter's Confession: "The Strategy of Economic Development" Revisited
WHEN I RECEIVED THE INVITATION to participate in the symposium as one
of the "pioneers" alongside Raul Prebisch, Gunnar Myrdal, Arthur Lewis,
and other such luminaries of development economics, my first reaction
was one of surprise. Not that I doubted my status as a luminary; but, in my
own mind, I still saw myself as a rebel against authority, as a secondgeneration
dissenter from the propositions that, while being themselves
novel and heterodox, were rapidly shaping up in the 1950s as a new
orthodoxy on the problems of development. Had my once daring and
insurgent ideas then become classic, respectable, that is, "distressingly
honorable" and "boring" in the manner of Nietzsche's plaint? Perhaps. In
any event, I must somewhat revise the picture I had of myself. Viewed in
perspective, my dissent, however strong, was in the nature of a demurrer
within a general movement of ideas attempting to establish development
economics as a new field of studies and knowledge.' My propositions were
at least as distant from the old orthodoxy (later called neoclassical economics)
as from the new. In retrospect, therefore, it is only natural that my
work should be lumped with the very writings I had chosen as my primary
targets
Comment Carlos F. Diaz Alejandro 112 Comment Paul P. Streeten
Sir Arthur Lewis: Development
Economics in the 1950s
THE MANDATE GIVEN TO ME is to advertise myself; to recall what I was
thinking about in the 1950s and how things have turned out. This has its
attractions since some of my earlier books are still in print and could do
with such a boost, but I have resisted this temptation. I have chosen instead
to write a brief sketch of the problems with which development economists
were then wrestling, with only occasional references to my own part.
I have also narrowed the agenda to the two major obsessions of the day:
what is the appropriate size of the industrial sector, and how is modernization
to be financed.
Comment Arnold C. Harberger
Gunnar Myrdal: International Inequality and
Foreign Aid in Retrospect
THIS PAPER is directed toward rendering an account of growing pangs of
conscience.' At the beginning of my research interest in the development
problems of underdeveloped countries, I gave unqualified support to the
idea that the developed countries should give financial assistance for their
development. In my own country, Sweden, I had been active in urging a
relatively generous and untied aid program for this purpose. Development
aid gradually reached the level, sometimes internationally declared to be a
goal, of 1 percent of the national income, and it was planned to reach even
higher in the future. Recent happenings in the underdeveloped countries
and in the world at large, however, have caused me to doubt whether I was
right. Political problems have regularly a moral kernel, and questions of
aid are essentially dependent upon moral judgment.
Comment Hla Myint
Raśl Prebisch: Five Stages in My Thinking on
Development
WHEN I STARTED MY LIFE as a young economist and professor during the
1920s, I was a firm believer in neoclassical theories. However, the first
great crisis of capitalism-the world Depression-prompted in me serious
doubts regarding these beliefs. It was the beginning of a long period of
heresies, as I tried to explore new views on development matters. The
second great crisis of capitalism, which we are all suffering now, has
strengthened my attitude.
In the long lapse of time between these two great crises, my thinking on
development has gone through five successive stages under the influence of
a changing reality and the broadening of my own experience.
During those hectic years of the Depression I had some influence on the
economic policy of my country, Argentina, first as under secretary of
finance and later with the Central Bank. During the 1930s I recommended
orthodox anti-inflationary measures to eliminate the fiscal deficit and
suppress inflationary tendencies, but at the same time I departed from
orthodoxy when I had to face a serious balance of payments disequilibrium
and advocated a resolute industrialization policy as well as other
measures to this end.
Comment Albert Fishlow Comment Jagdish N. Bhagwati
Paul N. Rosenstein-Rodan: Natura Facit Saltum: Analysis of the Disequilibrium Growth
Process
DURING THE SECOND WORLD WAR, I proposed in London the formation
of a group to study the problems of economically underdeveloped countries
instead of the more usual work on current economic problems related
to the war. If we were to emerge alive, we should want not to return to the
previous status quo but to form a better world. A study group was
organized at the Royal Institute for International Affairs (Chatham
House) and worked from 1942 till 1945 on problems of "underdeveloped
countries." This term appeared then for the first time. My 1943 article in
the Economic Journal served as a basic document for the group and is now
in many anthologies of economic studies of the Third World.'
Eastern and Southeastern Europe were selected as a model not because
of any special interest in those countries, but because their governments in
exile were in London and because Eastern and Southeastern Europe (like
Latin America) constitute a group of similar but not identical models. If
one compares India, Spain, and Ecuador everything is different. What is
cause and what is effect is anybody's guess. When one takes a group of
similar countries, they differ from each other in one or two but not in all
respects; it is then easier to examine what is cause and what is effect.
Comment Dragoslav Avramovic
Walt Whitman Rostow: Development: The Political Economy
of the Marshallian Long Period
WORK ON DEVELOPMENT THEORY AND POLICY in the 1950s forced me to
mobilize and bring together all I had learned in responding to the two large
questions I posed in 1933-34 to frame my professional agenda: the
application of economic theory to economic history, and the interplay of
economic forces with the other components of the life of whole societies.
The story begins in my first two years as an undergraduate at Yale. I
decided to major in history and wrote lengthy papers on facets of the
English Revolution of the seventeenth century and the French Revolution
which imparted some sense of the complexities of history and the inadequacy
of any simple theory of causation, including economic causation.
Comment Gerald Helleiner
Comment Azizali F. Mohammed
H. W. Singer: The Terms of Trade Controversy and the
Evolution of Soft Financing: Early Years in the U.N.
THE FIRST PART of this paper is mainly autobiographical, as seems justified
by the occasion: How did I come to be in the United Nations during those
early years, and why did I do what I did? The second part deals with my
1949-50 paper on the "Distribution of Gains between Investing and
Borrowing Countries," with the benefits of an extra thirty-two years of
hindsight. It is argued that the views then expressed have been well
vindicated, and that a reformulation in more contemporary terms would
now command increasing support. The third part deals with the story of
the Special United Nations Fund for Economic Development (SUNFED)
and the International Development Association (IDA), the World Bank
affiliate, as it appeared to one involved in the discussions of soft financing
of development in the 1950s and from the viewpoint of someone on the
U.N. side. According to my dictionary, a pioneer is "somebody who
prepares the road for the main body"; it is exactly my contention that the
"wild men" in the U.N. with their SUNFED prepared the road for the main
body, the World Bank.
Comment Bela Balassa
Jan Tinbergen: Development Cooperation as a Learning Process
My understanding is that this book deals with a twofold learning
process: the one through which, in the last half-century, all who participate
in the process of cooperation have gone and the one that goes on
inside each of us. The former could not have existed without the latter: in
order to change one's mind one has to be honestly convinced of the
necessity for accepting the change.
Like a number of others in the field of economics I deserted the subject of
my education, physics, under the influence of the phenomena of povertyto
begin with, in my own country. I made this switch in 1929, the very year
the Great Depression started. The latter created still more poverty, even in
the industrialized world. Intellectually, it was the cyclical component in
economic movements that first caught our minds. I had the privilege to
work, first, at the Netherlands Central Bureau of Statistics on business
cycle research, and from 1936 to 1938 at the League of Nations secretariat
at Geneva (so my first experience abroad was not exactly in a poor
country).
Comment Michael Bruno
Postscript
Paul P. Streeten: Development Dichotomies
THE WORLD IS DIVIDED into two groups of people: those who divide the
world into two groups of people, and those who don't. As I evidently
belong to the former, I believe that the nature of various divisions can
throw light on what has come to be known as the rise and decline of
development economics.
Albert Hirschman, in his stimulating contribution to the international
symposium on Latin America at Bar Ilan University in 1980,' used two
criteria for classifying development theories: whether they asserted or
rejected the claim of mutual benefits in North-South relations; and
whether they asserted or rejected the claim of monoeconomics that there is
a single economic discipline, applicable to all countries and at all times.
Using this classification, he derived four types of theories. Orthodox
(neoclassical) economics asserts both claims. Neo-Marxist and dependence
theories reject both claims. Development economists tend to reject
the monoeconomics claim-the reason for their existence calls for a
distinct subject-but to assert the mutual benefit claim, whereas paleo-
Marxists assert the monoeconomics claim (except insofar as class determines
consciousness) but reject the mutual benefit thesis.
Index
|