Globalization, Economic Development and Inequality
An Alternative Perspective
Edited by
Erik S. Reinert
President, The Other Canon Foundation, formerly at SUM –
The Centre for Development and the Environment, University
of Oslo, Norway
NEW HORIZONS IN INSTITUTIONAL AND EVOLUTIONARY
ECONOMICS
Edward Elgar
Cheltenham, UK • Northampton, MA, USA
Cover and Contents
List of contributors
Introduction
Erik S. Reinert
It is generally not recognized that two Nobel laureates in economics have
provided two conflicting theories of what will happen to world income
under globalization:
1. Based on the standard assumptions of neo-classical economic theory,
US economist Paul Samuelson ‘proved’ mathematically that unhindered
international trade will produce ‘factor-price equalization’, that
is that the prices paid to the factors of production – capital and labour
– will tend to be the same all over the world.
2. Based in an alternative dynamic tradition – which we here label
The Other Canon – Swedish economist Gunnar Myrdal was of the
opinion that world trade would tend to increase already existing differences
in incomes between rich and poor nations.
We would argue that the second approach easily incorporates the main elements
of evolutionary or neo-Schumpeterian economics, but with a
broader theoretical and historical perspective and with a broader agenda.
The aim of this book is to explore the contributions of today’s evolutionary
economics to the understanding of the increasing gap in global income
inequality, that is to broaden the normal perspective of neo-Schumpeterian
economics consciously into the realm of development economics.
PART I FOUNDATIONS OF AN ALTERNATIVE
THEORETICAL PERSPECTIVE
1.- The Other Canon: the history of Renaissance economics
Erik S. Reinert and Arno M. Daastøl
In economics, the theory that the world is flat has been coexisting for
centuries with the theory that the world is round. In this essay we shall argue
for the existence of an alternative to today’s mainstream theory: the continuation
of the canon that dominated the worldview of the Renaissance – The
Other Canon. Using a metaphor from Kenneth Arrow, ‘this tradition acts like
an underground river, springing to the surface every few decades’.
We argue that during the Cold War the ‘underground river’ of Renaissance
Other Canon economics all but disappeared from economic theory,
and that it is time to reintroduce it. Traditionally, The Other Canon has
been resurrected in times of crisis, such as national emergencies, which
bring production – not barter – into focus. This occurs, for example, when
an exclusive focus on barter has caused financial bubbles that subsequently
burst, when nations are engaged in serious catching up with the prevailing
world leader (as the United States, Germany and Japan were in the nineteenth
century, or as Korea was until recently), or when a war economy
forces a national political system to focus on production (of materials of
war). Today the urgency of a change of focus toward the Renaissance conception
of economics is particularly acute in the Third World and in formerly
communist Eastern Europe. Unfortunately, this is not where
economic theory is produced.
2.- Natural versus social sciences: on understanding in economics
Wolfgang Drechsler
"...it seems to me that the problem of the current mainstream, mathematical,
usually neoclassical approach to economics2 is two-fold. It is
flawed both practically and theoretically: practically because it does not
deliver, theoretically because it rests on premises that are problematic at
best, and extrapolates from them by equally questionable means. The argument
by its protagonists has been to excuse practical problems by pointing
to theoretical truth-value, and theoretical ones by pointing to practical
success.
This chapter concentrates on the theoretical problems. It rests on the
assumption, rather than tries to demonstrate, that mathematical economics
does not deliver; if one feels that it does, then one need not read on. But
of course the theoretical problems have a practical connection (see Kant
1992, pp. 23–5), because the purpose of pursuing economic scholarship is
not to create an aesthetically pleasing theoretical system, but rather to say
something meaningful and consequential, directly or indirectly, about
reality.
PART II THE STRATEGY OF SUCCESS: NINETEENTHCENTURY
UNITED STATES AND GERMANY
3.- The views of the German historical school on the issue of
international income distribution
Jürgen G. Backhaus
4.- Technical progress and obsolescence of capital and skills:
theoretical foundations of nineteenth-century US industrial
and trade policy
Michael Hudson
PART III THE STRATEGY OF FAILURE: LATE TWENTIETH CENTURY
DEINDUSTRIALIZATION AND THE
ECONOMICS OF RETROGRESSION
5.- Natural resources, industrialization and fluctuating standards
of living in Peru, 1950–97: a case study of activity-specific
economic growth
Santiago Roca and Luis Simabuko
6.- Globalization in the periphery as a Morgenthau Plan: the
underdevelopment of Mongolia in the 1990s
Erik S. Reinert
During the 50 years preceding the reforms of 1991, Mongolia slowly but
successfully built a diversified industrial sector. The share of agriculture in
the national product had declined steadily from 60 per cent in 1940 to about
16 per cent in the mid-1980s (International Monetary Fund 1991, p. 13).
However, the de facto Morgenthau Plan proved exceedingly successful in
deindustrializing Mongolia. In Mongolia 50 years of industry building was
virtually annihilated over a period of only four years, from 1991 to 1995,
not to recover again. In a majority of industrial sectors, production is down
by more than 90 per cent in physical volume since the country opened up
to the rest of the world, almost overnight, in 1991 (see Tables 6.2–6.4 in
Appendix 2).
PART IV TECHNICAL CHANGE AND THE DYNAMICS OF
INCOME INEQUALITY
7.- Technological revolutions, paradigm shifts and socioinstitutional
change
Carlota Perez
The last decades of the twentieth century were a time of uncertainty and
extremely uneven development. People in many countries and in most
walks of life felt uncertain about the future for themselves and their workplaces,
about the prospects for their own countries and for the world as a
whole. Inside each country and between countries there were strong centrifugal
trends generating unprecedented growth and wealth at one end of the
socio-economic spectrum and increasing poverty, deterioration and degradation
at the other. Among those old enough to remember, there was widespread
recognition that the erratic, uneven and unstable climate of the
1980s and 1990s was profoundly different from the ‘golden age’ of growth
of the 1950s and 1960s. This recognition is probably at the root of the
revival of interest in long waves.
This chapter puts forth an interpretation of the long-wave phenomenon
which offers to provide criteria for guiding social creativity in times such as
the present. In it, I define this period as one of transition between two distinct
technological styles – or techno-economic paradigms – and of construction
of a new mode of growth. Such construction would imply a
process of deep, though gradual, change in ideas, behaviours, organizations
and institutions, strongly related to the nature of the wave of technical
change involved.
8.- Income inequality in changing techno-economic paradigms
Chris Freeman
9.- Information technology in the learning economy: challenges
for developing countries
Dieter Ernst and Bengt-Åke Lundvall
10.- Diversity: implications for income distribution
David B. Audretsch
11.- Convergence, divergence and the Kuznets curve
Ådne Cappelen
Index 327
|