Human Development Report Office (HDRO) In preparation for the Human Development
Report every year, the HDRO commissions a number of experts to write papers on issues
related to the theme of the Report. The following is a compilation of selected Occasional
Papers written since 1992. Individually, each paper brings to light a key facet of human
development in different parts of the world. Together, they help establish a framework of
tools, concept and action to address the issue of human development worldwide.
Occasional Paper 32
Globalisation and liberalisation: Implications for poverty,
distribution and inequality
Kevin Watkins
1997
Introduction
Section One - Globalisation, poverty, and development
Part 1 - Elements of globalisation
- Trade, foreign investment, and speculation
Globalisation and distribution
Regionalism
Broad distributional questions
Part 2 - The Uruguay Round: an assessment
- Tariffs
Non-tariff barriers
Special and differential treatment
Textiles and clothing
Agriculture and food security
The distribution of benefits
Policy considerations: a post-Uruguay Round agenda
Box - The European Union
Part 3 - The international trade agenda: some missing issues
- Commodity markets
Debt and trade
Trade and Funding Development Assistance
Part 4 - Trade liberalisation, poverty, and distribution
- Trade liberalisation under NAFTA: the case of Mexican agriculture
Liberalisation and poverty in Mexico
Flexible labour
Regional factors
Trade and poverty: some concluding comments
Part 5 - Governments and markets
- Building domestic capacity: first - and second - generation NICs
Quality and quantity in foreign investment
Section Two - Trade, poverty and employment: issues for the industrialised world
Part 1 - Unemployment and inequality
- Political background
The US experience
The European Union
Wealth and poverty
Part 2 - North-South linkages: the evidence
- The skills gap
Distributional considerations
The technology thesis
Monetarist orthodoxy as a barrier to employment
The limits to flexible labour
Policy options
Part 3 - Social clauses and trade agreements
- The case for a social clause
An alternative framework
Box - The NAFTA 'side-accord'
The dangers of inaction
Section Three - New policies for new challenges
- Looking to the future
The national level
The international level
References
Introduction: The 'new order'
Some concepts come to define entire economic policy eras. For the 1990s,
'globalisation' will be recorded as the dominant theme. States are in retreat in the face
of powerful international economic forces which, we are constantly told, are
circumscribing their sphere of action. The resurgence of laissez faire economic
theory celebrates the fact. While carrying different connotations for different people,
globalisation encapsulates both a description of changing patterns of world trade and
finance, and an overwhelming conviction that deregulated markets will achieve optimal
outcomes for growth and human welfare. Seldom since the heyday of free trade in the
nineteenth century has economic theory inspired such certainty - and never has it been so
far removed from reality.
To the detached observer, noting the contrast between the presumed benefits of
globalisation and developments in the real world, the international economy displays a
number of worrying trends. Most obviously, poverty, mass unemployment, and inequality have
grown alongside the expansion of trade and foreign investment associated with
globalisation. In the developing world, poverty continues to increase in absolute terms,
and the gap between 'successful' and 'unsuccessful' countries is widening. In the
industrialised world, unemployment has reached levels not witnessed since the 1930s and,
in some countries, income inequalities are wider than at any time this century. In a world
of disturbing contrasts, the gap between rich and poor countries, and between rich and
poor people, continues to widen. It is increasingly apparent that this reality will not be
changed through growth alone. As the Pakistani economist Mahbub ul Haq once wrote:
In country after country, economic growth is being accompanied by rising disparities,
in personal as well as in regional incomes. In country after country, the masses are
complaining that development has not touched their ordinary lives. Very often, economic
growth has meant little social justice. It has been accompanied by rising unemployment,
worsening social services and increasing absolute and relative poverty (ul Haq 1976).
Written two decades ago, these words apply with equal force to one of the central myths
surrounding globalisation: namely, the conviction that the expansion of the global economy
is synonymous with an improvement in human welfare. Economists often explain the benefits
of growth through the familiar parable of the boat, insisting that all vessels rise on a
rising tide. The problem is that we are not all in the same boat. Some boats, containing
perhaps four-fifths of the population in the industrialised world, around two thirds of
the populations in the more successful East Asian countries, and the richest tenth of the
populations in Africa, Latin America, and other parts of Asia, are floating steadily.
Drinks are being served on the main deck. In the water around these vessels, other boats,
containing the majority of the world's people, are either barely afloat or sinking. Some
have already sunk, with their occupants floating in the water clutching flotsam for their
survival. The challenge for governments is to create a fleet capable of carrying all of
the world's people on a rising tide of shared prosperity and stability into the next
millennium.
Some aspects of globalisation have also offered advantages which are more illusory than
real. For instance, the extension of free trade and the integration of capital markets was
expected to generate massive foreign investment flows which would support economic
development, reduce poverty and enhance stability. In the event, investment flows have
been highly concentrated in a small number of countries. Moreover, optimism about
stability has been eroded by the chronic instability of unregulated financial markets. The
volatility of these markets has revealed the inability of existing international financial
institutions - notably the IMF - to create the conditions needed for a stable trade
environment (Stewart F and Fitzgerald E, 1996).
National governments have been unable to respond to the power of global financial
markets, which are now able to mount a direct challenge to the monetary sovereignty of
nations. The main reason is the power of foreign-exchange markets. Each week the daily
turnover on these markets outstrips the annual value of world trade flows. So far,
governments have not developed a clear strategy for dealing with this phenomenon. As a
result, their monetary policies are dictated not by employment and output objectives, but
by a concern to appease corporate pension-fund managers and currency speculators. The full
power of financial markets was highlighted during 1992 and 1993, when European currencies
were tossed about on a sea of speculative activity to which central banks were unable to
respond.
None of this is to deny that globalisation - or, more accurately, the deepening of
economic integration between countries - has contributed enormously to the creation of
wealth in some developing countries. The average income gap between south-east Asia and
the industrialised world is continuing to narrow, albeit from extremely wide levels, with
export growth driving economic expansion. In most countries in South-East Asia, the
benefits of economic growth are being widely distributed, as witnessed by sustained
reductions in poverty and improving human-welfare indicators. The problem, as we suggest
in this paper, is that the policies which have unleashed this potential in the success
stories of globalisation bear little resemblance to the neo-liberal idyll which now
dominates economic policy thinking. In particular, they were based upon a dynamic
interaction between states and markets, which many of the most vocal celebrators of
globalisation in the World Bank, the IMF and national governments now reject (Streeten P,
1993).
Learning from history
Internationally and nationally then, the world economy of the mid-1990s is
characterised by persistent poverty and widening inequalities. Current growth patterns
appear more likely to exacerbate than to alleviate these problems, creating the risk of
systemic collapse. This is a cause for international concern. If history offers one
lesson, it is that poverty and inequality do not create a fertile soil for political
stability, either at a national level or on the world stage. Recognition of this simple
fact dominated the vision of policy makers in the post-war period. With the poverty,
economic collapse, and international tensions caused by the Great Depression still a
recent memory, the Bretton Woods conference in 1944 marked a concern on the part of
governments to prevent a recurrence of those events. This implied a rejection not of
markets, but of the notion that unregulated markets could create the stability needed for
shared prosperity, or distribute the benefits of growth equitably. The spirit of the time
was captured by one of the architects of the Bretton Woods system:
All of us have seen the great economic tragedy of our time. We saw the worldwide
depression of the 1930s. We saw currency disorders develop and spread from land to land,
destroying the basis for international trade and international investment and even
international faith. In their wake, we saw unemployment and wretchedness - idle tools,
wasted wealth. We saw their victims fall prey, in places, to demagogues and dictators. we
saw bewilderment and bitterness become the breeders of fascism and finally of war. ( Dan
Morgantheau, cited in Van Dormeal)
When the history of the 1990s is written, the words 'idle tools, wasted wealth' will be
fitting accompaniments to 'globalisation'. Perhaps at no time since the 1930s has the need
for concerted international action to regulate global economic forces been so much in
evidence - and at no time since then has the vision of political leaders been so myopic.
Nowhere is this more evident than in international financial markets. One of the main
concerns of the founding fathers of the Bretton Woods system was to avoid a return to the
unfettered capital movements which caused such havoc in the inter-war period (Marquand D,
1996). That is why Keynes stressed the need institutional structures which would reduce
uncertainty and promote productive investment, while at the same time curbing speculative
activity. Such structures seem more relevant today than ever before. Yet the IMF, which
was created to fulfil the role of global financial regulator, has lacked the resources to
act as a lender of last resort to countries facing problems, and it has failed to address
the task of regulating international capital markets. Instead, it has used its policy
influence to promote the very deflationary responses to balance of payments pressures
which the architects of the Bretton Woods system sought to consign to history.
What is needed today is a vision as broad and ambitious as that which guided the
Bretton Woods meeting. Unfortunately, policy making in the mid-1990s appears to be led
either by the received wisdom of free-market economists, or by opinion polls. Governments
have collectively failed to address the challenges created by globalisation. Instead of
seeking to develop institutions capable of distributing global wealth more equitably, they
have allowed public-policy choices to be circumscribed by the presumed diktats of the
global market. Economic forces are running ahead of political responses. The same is true
at the national level. No government, so the argument runs, can seek to maintain welfare
states, pursue full employment, or protect basic social rights in a global economy where
capital is free to roam the world in pursuit of the largest profit margin. This approach
is all-pervasive - and it is misplaced. While it may be true that governments are less
powerful today than in the past, such defeatism is not justified by the facts of
globalisation. States are not rudderless boats driven by powerful currents of private
capital flows, and they retain the power to shape policies in the public interest.
Winners and losers
For developing countries, globalisation and greater openness to trade is widely
perceived as being doubly blessed. As for the developed countries, improved access to
markets and competition from imports are seen as sources of improved efficiency. The
additional benefit is that enhanced trade is supposed to open the door to increased
specialisation in labour-intensive goods. Liberalisation is thus not only good for growth,
but a means of reducing inequality through increased demand for labour, the main asset of
the poor. So deeply rooted is the conviction that globalisation is beneficial for human
development that the World Bank has developed a set of 'integration indicators'. These
purport to confirm a close and mutually reinforcing correlation between growth and
integration into world markets. To cite the 1996 Global Economic Prospects report:
"policies that are good for growth are also apt to be good for integration"
(World Bank, 1996).
It follows from this that the central role for governments is not to regulate markets,
but to facilitate their relentless expansion by removing barriers to trade and investment
(Ghai D and Alcantara C, 1994). National governments have been adopting this approach with
enthusiasm, especially in the developing world. At an international level, deregulation is
being pursued under the auspices of the World Trade Organisation (WTO). The Uruguay Round
agreement, now being implemented under the WTO, was widely regarded as a triumph for
multilateralism - and a decisive step towards the creation of a globalised international
economy, in which the benefits of free trade could be distributed to all countries.
Developing countries have been identified as among the prime beneficiaries, with important
gains for export earnings and poverty reduction widely anticipated (Safadi and Laird,
1996).
Such projections rest on highly exaggerated claims about globalisation and its presumed
benefits. Important changes are under way, but the global economy is not a construct of
the late twentieth century. Nor are its benefits as self-evident as is often assumed. In
this paper, we question some of the assumptions underlying the unbridled optimism about
the capacity of unregulated markets to sustain growth and address problems of poverty and
inequality. The aim is not to challenge the argument that the economic forces associated
with globalisation have the potential to enhance human development. There are enough
success stories to establish this fact beyond reasonable dispute. Our argument is rather
that, under existing international trade and finance rules, globalisation is marginalising
some countries, and actively threatening the livelihoods and welfare of vulnerable
communities. This was true of the 1980s, when market liberalisation emerged as a dominant
political and economic force under the auspices of IMF-World Bank adjustment programmes
(Berry 1996; Stewart 1993) - and it remains true of the 1990s.
Part of the evidence is to be found in the declining share in world trade and
investment suffered by many of the world's poorest countries. The forty-eight
least-developed countries now account for less than 0.3 per cent of world trade - half the
level two decades ago. Marginalised in trade these countries are also being bypassed by
private capital transfers, which have now displaced aid as the main conduit for
North-South financial flows. This pattern of distribution is not accidental. Inequality in
wealth mirrors a deep inequity in the rules governing world trade and finance, which have
been structured around the interests of the most developed countries. The Uruguay Round
agreement has not changed this picture. Issues of vital concern to many of the world's
poorest countries - notably the management of primary commodity markets and debt - were
conspicuous by their absence from the Uruguay Round agenda. Other problems were
inadequately addressed, including the problem of industrial and agricultural protectionism
in the developed countries. The distribution of benefits from the Uruguay Round agreement
reflects these realities, as we argue below. Meanwhile, traditional North-South divides
are being reinforced by growing inequalities within the developing world, with sub-Saharan
Africa falling further and further behind.
There is a parallel problem which is seldom discussed in the literature on
globalisation. For much of the post-war era there has been a political consensus in the
industrialised world that international trade expansion has positive outcomes for
employment and income levels. The slowdown in international trade growth in the 1970s and
a parallel rise in unemployment reinforced that view. Today, the consensus is breaking
down. Open unemployment in the OECD countries now affects 34 million people - ten times
the average for the 1960s. At the same time, income inequalities have widened in some
countries to levels not witnessed since the 1930s. Increasingly, globalisation is regarded
as a causal factor behind these trends, with competition from low-wage labour in
developing countries cited as the main culprit (Marquand, 1996).
While such concerns are as old as trade itself, the difference today is that powerful
political alliances have emerged, linking mass unemployment, income inequality, and
poverty in the industrial world to trade with developing countries. These alliances are
growing partly because of the failure of mainstream political parties to offer compelling
alternatives to their populist message; and partly because they reflect deeply-rooted
concerns. For poor communities in Europe and North America who are suffering the effects
of unemployment, rising wage inequality, and increasing poverty, sermons on the long-term
benefits of globalisation offer little comfort. By contrast, the overtly protectionist
alternative offered by 'anti-free trade' alliances (see Goldsmith, 1995), ill conceived
and potentially damaging to human development in the poorest countries as they may be,
have an obvious appeal.
This paper is structured as follows. Section One outlines the forces associated with
globalisation and considers their implications for poverty, inequality, and development.
Section Two examines the debate about the impact in the industrialised world of trade with
developing countries. This section concludes with a review of the cases for and against a
social clause in international trade agreements. Section Three examines some of the policy
options needed to underpin more equitable patterns of globalisation.
Section One: Globalisation, poverty, and
development
Part 1: Elements of globalisation
According to one school of thought, the globalisation of economic life marks a
watershed in history. Nation states are seen as an anachronistic left-over from a bygone
era, their sovereignty eroded by vast flows of goods and finance (Opmae 1994). The prime
movers of the new order are transnational companies, operating in a borderless world
linked by global production and consumption systems (Oman 1996). In the words of the
former US Labor Secretary, Robert Reich, "each nation's primary political task (is)
to cope with the centrifugal forces of the global economy" (Reich 1993). Such
assessments raise obvious questions. Most obviously: what is new about globalisation?
After all, the salient processes identified with globalisation pre-date the 1990s. Each
decade since the 1940s has been marked by the evolution of stronger interdependence. Trade
has been expanding faster than output since the 1950s, foreign investment has been growing
since the 1960s, and international financial markets started their dramatic expansion in
the 1970s. Each of these trends had contributed to the emergence of a global economy long
before the term 'globalisation' became fashionable.
In many respects, the idea that the globalised world economy is a recent product is a
conceit of the late twentieth century. From the early days of the industrial revolution,
manufacturers were concerned to create global markets. The company Dombey and Son in
Dickens' novel of the same name memorably believed that "rivers and seas were formed
to float their ships", and the Utilitarians who Dickens derided saw trade as part of
a "civilising mission". On a more self-interested level, the textile mills of
Lancashire depended on foreign markets to absorb over one third of their output by the end
of the nineteenth century. The establishment of the great trading companies formed in the
seventeenth century - such as the East India Company and the Royal Africa Company -
colonialism, and the opening of the Suez Canal, and the Union Pacific railroad, were all
defining moments in the creation of a global economy (Krugman P, 1995). By the 1920s,
steamships and railroads had created markets for standardised and globally traded goods
such as wheat, wool, and textiles. While it is true that the informatics revolution and
improved communications are playing an increasingly important role in reducing the
economic space between nations, the differences between steamship and aeroplanes, and
between telegraphs and computers, is arguably of more quantitative than qualitative
importance.
Even the most basic economic indicators used to gauge globalisation point to the need
for caution in evaluating the present one. Measured as a proportion of GDP, trade in
merchandise is no greater than it was before 1914 (Hirst and Thompson 1996). During the
inter-war years, the share of world output that entered into international trade declined;
it did not recover until after 1950. Developments since the mid-1980s mark a continuation
of the trend which resumed at that time, rather than a distinctive break with the past.
Much the same applies to capital flows. As a proportion of national income, capital flows
from Britain at the turn of the century represented a larger share of GDP than for any
major industrialised country in the 1990s. Such facts do not mean that there are no new
forces driving globalisation. They do, however, point to the need for the more specific
features of these forces to be defined.
Trade, foreign investment, and speculation
Although globalisation is not a new phenomenon, over the past decade it has been given
a new impetus, and taken new forms. Most obviously, trade has re-emerged as a dynamic
force for economic growth. In 1960 the share of trade (measured as the average of imports
and exports of goods and services) in the GDP of the industrialised countries averaged 12
per cent; it is now over 20 per cent. The growing economic importance of trade is
especially evident in the US, where the share of trade in GDP has almost tripled to 12 per
cent since 1960 (Krugman 1995). In parts of the developing world, trade growth has been
even more impressive. For East Asia it now represents around half of GDP. Even China,
virtually isolated from the world economy a quarter of a century ago, now exports 25 per
cent of GDP.
Recent interest in trade as an engine of globalisation reflects its recovery since the
mid-1980s. For a decade after 1974, the rate of increase of world trade growth fell to 3
per cent, from an average of over 5 per cent for the previous twenty years. The ratio of
world trade growth to output growth also fell, from 1.6 to 1.2. In the decade since the
mid-1980s, that ratio has climbed to 2.8. (World Bank, 1995). Even though trade growth
remains substantially below the 1964-1974 average, during the 1990s merchandise exports
have expanded at three times the rate of output. From a post-war perspective, the rate of
increase in the ratio of trade to GDP marks a return to the rising trend of the quarter of
a century up to 1974, during which it climbed from 7 per cent to 15 per cent (WTO 1996) of
global output. It remains to be seen whether this trend will be maintained. But if it
does, it will deepen the economic interdependence of all countries.
While the rising ratio of trade to GDP marks a return to the trend interrupted between
1974 and 1984, private capital flows have been expanding at a rate which is unparalleled
in the post-war period. Flows of foreign direct investment in 1994 exceeded $220bn, a
four-fold increase over the nominal level for 1981-1985, compared with an increase of a
little more than one half in the value of trade in goods and services. Between 1991 and
1993, the world stock of foreign direct investment grew about twice as fast as world-wide
exports (World Bank 1994).
Transnational companies
As the principal agents linking cutting-edge technology to low-cost labour,
transnational companies (TNCs) are one of the driving forces of globalisation. There are
an estimated 37,000 TNCs, controlling four times as many affiliated companies. Over 90 per
cent of these companies are based in the developed world. Collectively, they generated
sales of $4.8m in 1993, an estimated one third of which was conducted on an intra-company
basis. Foreign- investment activity is dominated by a core group of around 100 TNCs, with
the largest one hundred accounting for one-third of the $2.4 trillion in global investment
stock (UNCTAD 1995b).
The recent boom in foreign-investment activity reflects a process of corporate
restructuring. Increasingly, companies are re-ordering their production on a global basis,
establishing a presence in fast-growing markets, and shifting production from high-wage to
low-wage economies. The resulting trade and investment flows have accelerated the movement
of goods, services, and investment across national frontiers, reducing the economic
distance between nations - an important aspect of globalisation (Oman C 1996). In many
respects, however, this is also more of a quantitative than qualitative change, since
increasing economic interdependence has been a feature of the post-war economy.
If there is a single defining feature of globalisation in the late twentieth century,
it is the increasing ease with which technology can accompany capital across borders. This
shift threatens to break irrevocably the link between high productivity, high technology,
and high wages. It is now possible for transnational companies to combine through their
investment activity high productivity, high technology, and low wages (Harvard Business
Review 1993). Once again, however, it is important to set this development in a broader
context. Comparisons of wage levels unadjusted for productivity differences are
particularly misleading. Thus average hourly labour costs vary between $12-25 dollars in
the industrialised world, with Britain at the lower end of the spectrum and Germany at the
higher end. But if real wages are measured against productivity, wage costs for the US
(where hourly rates are around $16) are lower than for the Philippines (average hourly
rate less than $1) (The Economist 1995). This productivity gap reflects a wide array of
factors, ranging from skill levels to infrastructure and access to capital. But while
differences remain, there are already signs that the productivity gap is narrowing. For
instance, Mexico's productivity per worker has risen from one fifth to one third of the
level in the USA between 1989 and 1993, in part as a consequence of increased foreign
investment geared towards production for the US market. Meanwhile, the average wage gap
has narrowed far more slowly, with the Mexican wage still only one sixth of the US level
(The Economist 1994a).
The changing structure of labour market competition between North and South is part of
a broader picture. Four decades ago, product markets in international trade were largely
segmented. Broadly, developing countries produced unprocessed goods, while the developed
countries monopolised the export of manufacturing. Labour markets were similarly
segmented, with the most productive technologies being utilised in the high-wage economies
of the North (Stewart, 1994). This model began to break down in the 1960s, as developing
countries emerged as competitors in labour-intensive manufacturing markets. During the
1980s, however, more profound shifts occurred, as the informatics revolution made
technologies increasingly transferable between countries, and as barriers to investment
were removed. It is these changes which have made it possible to link the most productive
technologies with low-cost labour. To take one illustration, Ford's plant at Hermosillo in
Mexico (see below) has productivity levels which are comparable with those of the most
modern plants in Detroit (Carillo, 1995).
Outward investment
Recent trends in US investment illustrate the profound impact of globalisation. In
1994, the US outward stock of foreign investment reached a record 9 per cent of GDP, as
American TNCs established a growing presence in foreign markets. The North American Free
Trade Association (NAFTA) has been a focal point of this investment, with the level of US
investment stock in Mexico increasing from $8bn in 1989 to $16bn in 1995. The linkages
between trade and investment flows are much in evidence, with one quarter of US-Mexican
trade now being conducted on a intra-firm basis. Restructuring through direct foreign
investment (DFI) has gone further in the US than in the other OECD countries. World-wide
sales by the foreign affiliates of American TNCs amount to 250 per cent of US exports,
well over double the industrial-country average (UNCTAD 1996a). This suggests the scope
for an accelerated drive towards globalisation in the medium term as Japanese and European
TNCs 'catch up'.
The process has already started. At present the total flow of DFI from Japan is only
slightly more than US flows to Mexico. But many Japanese firms see shifting production
overseas, notably to South-East Asia, as a strategy for penetrating new regional markets
and expanding exports to Europe and the US. In 1994, Japanese investment in overseas plant
reached the equivalent of almost one quarter of domestic investment - and that ratio will
rise. Similarly, over half of all companies in Germany, which has a ratio of overseas
sales by foreign affiliates to domestic exports less than one quarter of that of the US,
are reported to be planning a transfer of production to other countries (Financial Times,
8 December 1996).
The phenomenal concentration of corporate power within the global economy, and the
economic exchanges which underpin it, provide an important pointer to the second decisive
feature of globalisation in the mid-1990s: namely, the production of goods in a growing
number of stages, adding a small amount of value at each stage (Krugman P 1995). In the
classic model of heavy industry during the inter-war period, the components making up a
Ford motor car were assembled in one integrated factory in Detroit. Today, the components
in a typical Ford gear box will have passed through three or four countries. The same
applies to everything from fridges to computers and garments. Fifty years ago, exported
consumer good typically would be transferred between countries only once. Today, it is
exported many times. Goods produced in one country may be assembled from components
produced in other countries, which in turn comprise sub-components produced in yet other
countries. This segmentation of production is both a cause and effect of the increasing
mobility of capital and technology.
Currency speculation
Foreign-investment flows have overtaken foreign trade as an engine of world growth.
Through such investment, TNCs are exerting an ever-more powerful and visible influence on
the future of countries and their citizens. Less visible, but infinitely more powerful,
are the world's financial markets. The deregulation of capital markets, the development of
a wide range of financial products, cheap telecommunications, and computer equipment have
fundamentally shifted the balance of power between governments and financial speculators.
In the mid-1970s, the daily turnover of foreign exchange in the world's money markets
amounted to around $1bn. Official currency reserves were equivalent to around 15 per cent
of this total, giving governments considerable power to counter speculative activity.
Today, daily turnover on foreign-exchange markets has reached $1.2 trillion, having
doubled since 1989 (Financial Times 1996). Official currency reserves now amount to less
than 1 per cent of this total. This profound change is another defining feature of
globalisation.
In the past few years, there have been some striking demonstrations of the inability of
governments to withstand speculative onslaughts. The breaching of the Exchange Rate
Mechanism in 1992 and the collapse of the Mexican peso in 1994 are the two most powerful
examples. Both episodes demonstrated that markets can change their views with astonishing
speed, and that even the most powerful central banks are unable to resist concerted
attacks. During 1992-1993 the Bundesbank spent some $130bn in defence of the currencies of
six of its EU partners. The combined IMF quotas of these countries was $23bn, underlining
the increasingly marginal role of the IMF in stabilising markets. So far, governments have
failed to develop policies capable of controlling these markets. Instead, they have
resorted to increasingly restrictive monetary and inflation targets, with interest rates
geared towards their attainment. The criteria for economic and monetary convergence in the
EU reflect this approach. In consequence, the expansion of output and demand has been
relegated to the policy back-burner, with disastrous consequences for employment in the
industrialised world (UNCTAD 1996c). Developing countries have also suffered from the
depressed state of Northern demand for their exports.
Globalisation and distribution
Globalisation is revolutionising economic relations between countries. But it is a
revolution built upon powerful elements of continuity, as well as change. Developed
countries, representing 20 per cent of the world's population, typically account for
between three quarters and four fifths of foreign investment, and for a similar share of
world GDP and exports. The Group of Seven countries alone account for half of world trade
flows. These shares have changed only marginally over the past two decades - and there is
no indication that new patterns of globalisation will erode this concentration of power.
Within the developing world, there has been a widening inequality in the distribution
of benefits from international trade. Overall ratios of trade to GDP have fallen in 44
countries over the past decade (World Bank, 1996). Sub-Saharan Africa has the lowest and
fastest- declining ratio. A further 17 countries experienced only modest rises. At the
other end of the spectrum, the ratio of trade to GDP has increased by over 1 per cent a
year for over two decades in East Asia. These changes matter, because trade is becoming an
increasingly important engine of growth - and because over one billion people live in
countries which are being left behind by that engine, decoupled from the rise in average
incomes.
Export growth-rates in excess of 9 per cent per annum have widened the already large
gap between East Asia and the rest of the developing world. In the first three years of
the 1990s, per capita incomes in East Asia rose at three times the average for all
developing countries, and seven times the average for sub-Saharan Africa. Thus while trade
expansion has enabled a significant number of developing countries to narrow the gap
between themselves and the developed world, albeit from a low starting point, others are
falling behind. For instance, the 48 least-developed countries (LDCs) have suffered a
steady decline in their share of world trade since the 1970s (UNCTAD 1996a). In 1993,
these countries accounted for a mere 0.4 per cent of world exports - almost half the level
in 1980. This helps to explain why the poorest fifth of the world's population have seen
their share of world income decline by almost one quarter since 1960, to 3.6 per cent of
the total. Within this broad picture of East Asian success and LDC failure, there is a
wide range of variations. Even so, trade is becoming an increasingly important engine of
inequality as well as of growth. Globalisation is unlikely to reverse this trend towards
marginalisation, and it may accentuate it.
In the case of manufacturing trade, the share of industrialised countries in global
value-added has fallen since the 1960s, but only to 80 per cent. Moreover, almost all of
the shift in manufacturing activity has occurred in east and south-east Asia, whose market
share has doubled from just over 4 per cent in 1970 to 11 per cent in 1995. After growing
strongly in the 1970s, Latin America's share has declined over the past 25 years, and
sub-Saharan Africa's already tiny 0.6 per cent share in 1970 has been halved. According to
UNIDO's projections, these trends will continue into the twenty-first century, with East
Asia and China almost doubling their world market-share over the decade to 2005, and Latin
America and sub-Saharan Africa continuing to stagnate.
Foreign-investment gaps
In part, trends in manufacturing-export performance can be traced to direct
foreign-investment activity. As a group, developing countries have shared in the rapid
growth of foreign investment, accounting for 37 per cent of total direct foreign
investment in 1994. Between 1990 and 1995, total private capital flows to developing
countries almost quadrupled to $167bn (UNCTAD, 1996). The largest element in these flows
has been direct foreign investment, which reached $90bn in 1995 and is now the single
largest source for financial transfers to developing countries. However, just ten
countries received over three quarters of all transfers, with China alone accounting for
more than one third. Thus foreign-investment resources are being concentrated on those
countries - such as Thailand, Indonesia, Colombia, Malaysia, Taiwan - which are performing
most strongly in international trade. Eight countries that account for 30 per cent of
developing-country GDP absorb around two thirds of total DFI flows. At the other extreme,
the 48 LDCs received around $800m in foreign investment in 1993 - roughly the same size as
flows into Brazil, and less than 1 per cent of total transfers to developing countries
(UNCTAD 1995).
One recent study has attempted to estimate the spread of foreign investment between the
world's citizens, while correcting for the size of the Chinese population (Hirst and
Thompson 1996). Taking together the industrialised 'triad' of North America, Europe, and
Japan and adding the eight Chinese coastal provinces and Beijing, the study conducted that
around 28 per cent of the world's population receives over 90 per cent of foreign direct
investment. In other words, two thirds of the world's population is virtually written off
the map as far as foreign investment is concerned. As investment activity becomes
increasingly concentrated in this core group of countries, the idea that benefits will
eventually trickle down through the economic global economic system appears at best
far-fetched - and at worst an exercise in delusion.
This has important distributional implications. While foreign direct investment
represents a relatively small proportion of total investment and national income,
accounting for 3 per cent of GDP in East Asia and 1 per cent in Latin America, it is an
important conduit for the transfer of new technologies. As international trade becomes
more and more knowledge- intensive, access to these technologies becomes increasingly
important to future competitiveness - and the difficulties faced by LDCs in attracting
foreign investment threaten to exclude them from the major source of technological
innovation, exacerbating their technological weakness in the process (UNCTAD, 1996).
Foreign investment in the poorest countries is deterred by a variety of forces, including
weak infrastructure, the small size of domestic and regional markets, shortages of skilled
workers, low levels of education, and political instability. Once again, globalisation is
at least as likely to exacerbate as to resolve these problems, as investment resources are
concentrated on stronger economies.
Economic growth, trade expansion, and access to foreign investment tend to be mutually
reinforcing, offering the potential for countries to enter virtuous cycles of rising
average incomes; and posing the threat of a vicious circle of decline. To take one
dimension of international finance, new commitments of export credits to developing
countries doubled between 1990 and 1995 to $80bn. These flows play a potentially important
role in financing the imports upon which export-competitiveness depends. Yet sub-Saharan
Africa, the region in which access to imports is most constrained, is being bypassed by
the most important source: financial transfers, including export credits. In 1994,
sub-Saharan Africa received FDI flows worth $1.8bn, or the equivalent of flows to New
Zealand. As a result, the region is becoming increasingly dependent upon concessional aid
flows which, in contrast to private investment flows, are in decline. In nominal terms,
aid flows have changed little since 1993, but they have fallen by 3 per cent per annum in
real terms. In 1995, net flows of overseas development assistance (ODA) fell to their
lowest level as a proportion of donor GNP since 1973, and budgetary pressures, allied to
the unwillingness of governments to defend aid budgets, make it unlikely that this trend
will be reversed (OECD 1996).
Regionalism
In parallel with the movement towards globalisation, regionalism has acquired a new
lease of life since the early 1990s. Out of 98 preferential trade arrangements reported to
the GATT up to 1995, one third were established during the previous five years (WTO 1995).
During the early 1990s, the revival of regionalism was widely perceived as a threat to
the multilateral trading system. Developing countries were concerned at the prospect of a
'fortress Europe' emerging from Single European Market. Meanwhile, pessimism about the
prospects of the Uruguay Round accelerated the emergence of new trade groupings committed
to regional and bilateral liberalisation. The creation of the Asia Pacific Economic Forum
(APEC) and the conclusion in 1993 of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA)
between the USA, Canada, and Mexico reflected these fears, as did the US drive to extend
NAFTA into a hemispheric free-trade area in Latin America during 1994. The spectre of
three mutually hostile trade blocs centred on Europe, North America, and Japan, with a
proliferation of discriminatory arrangements, loomed large behind the Uruguay Round, and
probably helped to prevent its collapse (de Melo and Pagariya, 1992).
'Open regionalism'
Since the conclusion of the Uruguay Round, the political impetus behind regional trade
has continued. In some cases, pre-existing preferential arrangements have been revived.
The Central American Common Market (CACM), the Andean Group, and the Caribbean Community
(CARICOM) were given new leases of life, as were regional integration strategies in Africa
under the Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa (COMESA), and the Southern African
Development Community (SADC) in Africa. So far, the revival of these arrangements has been
more cosmetic than real (Bouzas, 1995). In other cases - such as MERCOSUR - dynamic new
alliances have emerged. In general, however, the new order is founded upon 'open
regionalism' and liberalisation, rather than the principle of increased protection against
non-associate members (Mistry P 1995).
This is an important - and almost universal - departure from the regionalism of the
1960s, when preferential tariff systems were seen an integral part of import-substituting
industrialisation strategies. During the second half of the 1990s, regionalism is likely
to evolve in a manner which reinforces globalisation, accelerating the removal of trade
and investment restrictions in a complex patchwork of trading arrangements integrated into
a process of multilateral liberalisation under the WTO. It is certainly difficult to see
regionalism offering an alternative to globalisation. On tariffs, the 10-20 per cent
average levels agreed under the Uruguay Round for developing countries leaves little scope
for regional initiative. The major possible exceptions are textiles and agriculture,
although regional groupings such as ASEAN and MERCOSUR have so far failed to overcome
deeply entrenched internal differences in these areas. With regard to investment, the
development of a multilateral investment code under the WTO is likely to go much further
than any regional initiative. Moreover, the WTO sets limits on the preferences which
regional groups can provide (Page S 1995). The Uruguay Round agreement demands that
regional groupings must aim at completely free trade among their members within "a
reasonable length of time", without raising barriers against other countries.
MERCOSUR
Among the most significant of the new groupings to emerge is the Southern Cone Common
Market (MERCOSUR), linking Brazil, Argentina, Paraguay, and Uruguay, is a customs union,
with a common external tariff, in January 1995. These countries form a market of 200
million people, and account for around one half of Latin America's GDP. The potential for
the creation of a dynamic integrated trade space is clearly enormous. It remains to be
seen whether MERCOSUR realises that potential, but the liberalisation measures taken so
far are more than cosmetic. Trade among the MERCOSUR countries has increased by over 250
per cent since 1990, led by a boom in trade between Brazil and Argentina. The mutually
reinforcing tendencies of regionalism and globalisation are much in evidence. For
instance, Japanese car companies have invested heavily in Argentinean plant to produce for
export to Brazil (Financial Times, 25 January 1995). At the same time, MERCOSUR has
boosted foreign investment from countries in the region, in many cases through
partnerships with foreign TNCs. The scope for MERCOSUR to act as a force for
liberalisation in the future is underlined by the participation of Chile, which joined as
an associate member in 1995 and is now an important source of foreign investment within
the group.
South-east Asia
In regional terms, south-east Asia has remained the most dynamic site for trade and
investment. Foreign-investment flows into the region have more than doubled since the late
1980s, rising to $44bn in 1994, and exports have grown at over 10 per cent a year.
Intra-regional flows have become increasingly important. Trade between developing
countries in the region has risen from 25 per cent to 40 per cent of their total trade
since 1980 (Asian Development Bank, 1996). Foreign-direct investment originating in the
region is also growing in importance. It now accounts for over one third of total stock.
Regional trade initiatives and the liberalisation of import and investment regimes make it
likely that the above trends will continue. For instance, in 1992 the seven ASEAN
countries formed the Asian Free Trade Agreement, which aims to create a free trade zone by
the year 2008.
Investment flows are becoming an increasingly powerful force for regional integration
in Asia, as companies respond to changes in relative labour costs and opportunities for
production and export. Over one half of South Korea's foreign investment is now directed
towards Asia, with China, Indonesia and Vietnam the main growth points. Taiwanese and
Singapore-based companies are also relocating. Between them, these two countries and South
Korea account for more than twice as much of the foreign investment going into Vietnam,
one of the region's fastest-growing sites for investment, as do the USA and Japan. Second-
generational newly industrialised countries (NICs) are also restructuring. For instance,
Malaysian companies are emerging as major investors in Vietnam and the Philippines,
relocating in response to rising wages in the domestic economy (Business Review 1996).
Growth triangles and cross-regional initiatives
Sub-regional initiatives are fuelling the drive towards more open trade, shaping the
local experience of globalisation in the process. Examples are the East Asean Growth Area
(Brunei, Indonesia, Malaysia, and the Philippines), and 'growth triangle' arrangements
such as the Singapore-Johor-Riau triangle (involving Indonesia, Malaysia, and Singapore)
and the Indonesia, Malaysia, Thailand triangle (Asia Development Bank 1992). At varying
speeds, these triangles are creating important economic linkages, as witnessed by the
transfer of electronic assembly operations from Singapore and Malaysia to Indonesia, the
Philippines, and Vietnam.
Superimposed on this regional jigsaw is an equally complex system of linkages between
regions. In 1995, MERCOSUR and the EU signed a landmark agreement which commits the two
groups to the gradual establishment of a free-trade zone. That agreement also links Europe
to the web of arrangements between MERCOSUR and other Latin American countries and
groupings. More significant still has been the emergence of the Asian Pacific Economic
Cooperation (APEC) forum, which links three of the world's largest economies (the USA,
Japan, and Canada) to Asia and Latin America. The fourth APEC summit was held in Manila,
the Philippines, in 1996, with the 18 countries represented collectively accounting for
over half the world's GDP, 40 per cent of its total population, and half of world
merchandise trade. It many respects, APEC remains an embryonic consultative group, even
though its ultimate goal of full trade and investment liberalisation by 2020 is an
ambitious one. So far, practical action has taken the form of highly publicised
tariff-reduction measures, most of which have been within the parameters set by the
Uruguay Round. What is important about APEC is less its concrete achievements to date than
its potential for linking MERCOSUR, NAFTA, and AFTA in a process of global market
liberalisation.
It will be apparent from the above account that one region is conspicuous by its
absence from the more dynamic regional alliances: namely, sub-Saharan Africa. This raises
the danger that the world's poorest region, with the highest concentration of poverty,
will be excluded from the trade and investment processes underpinning global and economic
prosperity into the next century. During the first four years of the 1990s, East Asia's
GDP grew at five times the rate for sub-Saharan Africa, and Latin America's at twice the
rate. The resulting divergence in average incomes will be further widened if sub-Saharan
Africa remains a marginalised participant in international trade.
Broad distributional questions
It has become an article of faith that liberalisation and deeper integration into the
global economy are good for growth and for poverty reduction. For developing countries,
globalisation is seen as the door to new opportunities - wider markets for trade, private
capital inflows, improved access to technology, and greater efficiency. It is taken as
axiomatic that 'outward-looking' reforms - a euphemism for liberalisation and deregulation
- are the key to improved economic prospects. East Asia is cited as evidence in support of
this view. Allied to the belief that globalisation accelerates growth is the parallel
conviction that poor people will be the main beneficiaries. This is because trade is
presumed to increase returns to labour, the most abundant asset of poor people.
Reality is more prosaic. Globalisation does create opportunities for wealth
enhancement, but those opportunities are not equitably distributed among countries - or
among people. At the national level, as the evidence presented earlier suggests, some
countries have been unable to exploit the opportunities provided by trade and foreign
investment. For sub-Saharan Africa, the ratio of trade to GDP is lower than it was twenty
years ago. Meanwhile, the region's declining share of world markets has cost it the
equivalent of $60bn per annum in current dollar terms over the past fifteen years. To put
this figure in context, it represents around three times the flow of development
assistance received by African governments.
What, then, are the conditions for successful participation in the global economy? This
question is examined in more detail in Part 5, where the experience of south-east Asia is
considered. In broad terms, however, seven interlocking conditions are important.
-
- Sensible policies. Blanket protectionism, over-valued exchange rates, excessive taxation
of producers, and over-regulation are policies which have had disastrous consequences for
economic growth in Africa, and have contributed to the region's deteriorating trade
performance. The south-east Asian model illustrates the importance of allowing markets to
work within a viable regulatory framework, including selective and time-bound protection
and investment controls.
- Avoiding 'big bangs'. Radical across-the-board trade liberalisation is unlikely to have
the desired economic results, and highly likely to lead to unnecessary social costs.
Experience suggests that imports are likely to increase rapidly, while exports increase
more slowly. While old-style import-substitution strategies may have been misplaced, it is
important not to throw out the baby with the bath water. The problem with these strategies
was that they granted protection indiscriminately and failed to provide appropriate
incentive structures. Selective intervention in response to market failures and the need
for longer adjustment periods should not be ruled out. There are two broad strands to a
viable alternative. The first involves liberalising imports of capital goods needed to
generate increased exports and employment more rapidly than the liberalisation of imports
which compete with labour-intensive local industries. The second strand would include the
use of time-bound and performance-related protection for potentially viable industries.
- The development of diversified export structures with progress up the value-added chain.
South-east Asia's success was based upon diversification and policies which established a
dynamic comparative advantage in higher value-added sectors. Central to these policies
were coherent industrial-development strategies, in which import controls and investment
regulation were geared towards raising productivity, expanding employment, and
competitiveness in world markets.
- Access to imports. Export competitiveness depends upon local industries absorbing new
technologies. Limited foreign-exchange cover, chronic balance-of-payments deficits, and a
large debt overhang impose obvious constraints upon import capacity. So too, does
dependence upon volatile primary-commodity markets, because of the resulting exchange-rate
instability. Access to finance is of crucial importance to trade expansion. In this
context, the stagnation of bilateral and multilateral assistance to the poorest countries
poses acute problems.
- Access to markets. Trade links high-income countries to low-income countries, expanding
the market in which producers operate. In order to derive maximum benefits from trade,
developing countries need access to markets in the industrialised world. This remains
limited across a wide range of sectors, especially in the labour-intensive sectors which
are of greatest relevance to developing countries.
- Access to infrastructure. Production for world markets requires a marketing
infrastructure, including roads, ports, and telecommunications. Movement up the
value-added chain typically requires an increasingly sophisticated infrastructure. Public
investment in this area is therefore vital.
- Skills upgrading. As trade becomes increasingly knowledge-intensive, so the demands upon
workforces will increase. Investment in education and the attainment of universal primary
education would appear to be of crucial significance, as would investment in training, and
research and development.
Establishing the effects of globalisation on poverty reduction and income distribution
in respect of people, as distinct from countries, is more difficult. But crude
extrapolation based upon the conviction that trade and investment growth is inherently
beneficial to poor people is not helpful. Reduced to its essentials, globalisation
integrates countries and people into a wider market. However, the relative weakness of the
local economies, especially in the developing world, and the strength of global
market-forces means that adjustment to world market pressures poses tough challenges. In
the domestic market, local producers have to adapt to competition from imports produced in
countries which have access to more sophisticated technologies, more capital resources,
and a more skilled workforce. Foreign-investment flows can re-shape relations between
social groups and regions. The resulting distribution of costs and benefits will reflect
factors such as income distribution, the distribution of assets, levels of education, and
intra-household gender relations.
Problems of distribution: access to assets
Other things being equal, it is not difficult to show that countries benefit from trade
and specialisation. The problem is that other things, and notably the distribution of
economic and political power, are not equal. Poverty is partly about a lack of assets. In
countries where wealth is closely tied to land, disadvantaged households are typically
land-poor or landless, and they lack access to other productive assets such as capital,
technology, and water. They also tend to be concentrated in areas which are ecologically
degraded and geographically isolated, with limited access to markets. It follows that, in
the absence of wider redistributive measures, increasing returns to export-crop production
will have limited benefits for the poor.
Consider, for example, the current growth strategy in Zimbabwe (World Bank, 1995b).
Under the country's structural adjustment programme, commercial farmers have been given
extensive tax and foreign-exchange incentives to expand production for exports. Crops such
as tobacco, flowers, and off-season vegetables have been identified as growth points, and
public investment resources been concentrated in these sectors. The problem, from a
poverty- reduction perspective, is that Zimbabwe has one of the world's most unequal
patterns of land distribution. Some 4,400 farms and ranches occupy one third of the
country's arable land, including the bulk of the land in areas of high rainfall. These
farms, which average over 2,200 hectares in size, produce more than 85 per cent of the
country's marketed output. In contrast, an estimated 2 million farms are concentrated in
the densely populated, highly degraded communal-farm areas. The majority of these farms
are less than two hectares in size.
Only a small minority of communal farmers are in position to exploit the opportunities
presented by export markets. Most are unable to grow enough food to feed their family
members. In the poorest areas, marketing infrastructure is non-existent. Even if it were
available, soil erosion and inadequate access to water would rule out the production of
export crops. The World Bank itself has conceded that most producers in these areas will
not be able to participate in the export-growth drive. Yet the vast majority of the 2.6
million Zimbabweans who are unable to meet their basic needs live in the communal farm
areas. Not only will poverty within this group intensify, but Zimbabwe will become an
increasingly unequal society. Given that it is already the world's most unequal society as
measured by the Gini coefficient (0.57 compared with 0.61 for South Africa), this is an
obvious source of concern.
The Zimbabwean case graphically illustrates the importance of concentrating upon the
distribution of increments to income associated with growth, rather than upon aggregate
growth rates. In countries characterised by a high degree of inequality such as Brazil,
the Philippines, and Mexico, the opportunities for poverty alleviation created by
globalisation will be missed in the absence of redistributive reforms, even where some
income trickles down to the poor. One recent World Bank study estimates that a
deterioration in income distribution in Bangladesh during the 1980s resulted in the
head-count index of poverty falling by 0.3 per cent, rather than the 1.9 per cent which
would have resulted had the income-distribution curve remained unchanged (World Bank
1996).
There are other reasons for questioning the simple extrapolation methods used by the
World Bank and others. Encouraging export-crop production may imply a concentration of
production on richer regions of the country (as is happening in Mexico and Zimbabwe). It
may precipitate a land grab in which the rich and politically powerful dispossess the
powerless (as in Brazil). In the Philippines, vulnerable urban squatter communities, such
as those living on Manila's notorious Smokey Mountain, have been displaced to make way for
the warehouses of foreign investors. Men may increase their cash incomes at the expense of
women. Where export production is associated with mechanisation, it can reduce labour
requirements and thus wage incomes.
On the other hand, export production can create jobs. This is clearly an important
potential benefit. However, the quality of the jobs in question is important. In much of
Latin America, export-led growth has been associated with low wages and, insecure
employment, with women workers facing particularly exploitative conditions (Kay C 1995).
Not only is the insecurity and vulnerability associated with such employment bad for
poverty reduction, it is also bad for income inequality.
It is true that all of these processes relate as much to commercialisation in general
as to globalisation in particular. One cannot draw general conclusions based on the
presumed benefits or disbenefits of trade in the absence of specific information about
particular situations. In broad terms, however, four conditions are of paramount
importance in ensuring that globalisation contributes to poverty alleviation.
- Access to assets. Policies to redistribute land and improve tenancy rights are critical
to ensuring that agricultural export-growth benefits the poor. Credit can also help the
poor to accumulate assets and engage in markets. Developing financial institutions for the
poor to mobilise savings and investment is thus crucial.
- Improving access to infrastructure and technology. Public investment in technology and
infrastructure is critical in raising incomes and reducing poverty. Removing biases
against small farmers demands the development of indigenous capacity to do research built
on genuine participation and investment in training extension workers. Poor farmers
invariably have less access to roads, electricity, and water than richer farmers, which
restricts their ability to grasp market opportunities. Public investment in poor people
and marginal areas is needed to correct this imbalance.
- Investing in people. There is overwhelming evidence that human capital is one of the
keys to reducing poverty. It is also one of the keys to successful and equitable
participation in global markets. Poorly educated people suffering from ill health do not
provide a foundation for building prosperity in a competitive global economy. In most of
the countries failing in world markets, there is too little investment in human capital,
and this increases the probability that the country and the next generation of its
citizens will remain poor.
- Protecting labour. For people who participate in global markets by selling their labour,
there are two determinants of the benefits which result: incomes and security. Employment
practices which drive down wages to the point where they barely meet basic subsistence
needs are economically inefficient, and they are socially inequitable. Similarly,
'flexible' labour practices which disregard the most basic employment rights will diminish
the potential benefits of trade and investment flows.
Part 2: The Uruguay Round: an assessment
The Uruguay Round of multilateral trade negotiations, which was concluded with the
signing of the Final Act in 1994, was the longest of the eight rounds held under the
auspices of the GATT. It was also the most ambitious. Even before its conclusion, the
Uruguay Round was widely celebrated as the dawn of a new era, with enormous gains for all
countries confidently predicted, including the poorest. The ministerial declaration which
launched the Round included in its first objective the extension of benefits from
international trade to developing countries as one of the major aims of the negotiations.
Tariff reductions, the lowering of non-tariff barriers, the integration of textiles into a
new set of trade rules, the liberalisation of agriculture, and the maintenance of special
and differential treatment for developing countries are commonly cited as evidence that
this objective was achieved and that the Final Act has created a framework for the more
equitable distribution of benefits from world trade.
In fact, the benefits accruing to developing countries from the Uruguay Round are
considerably more limited than such accounts suggest. Under the old GATT regime, trade
liberalisation was geared towards policies and sectors (mainly tariffs on manufactured
goods) of interest to the industrialised countries (Williams, 1994). Under the new regime,
the benefits of tariff reduction have again been weighted in favour of the industrialised
world. Moreover, the move towards full liberalisation in textiles and agriculture is
considerably more restricted in practice than the principles enshrined in the WTO
framework might indicate. An additional problem for the poorest countries is that many of
the structural problems which hamper their capacity to benefit from more liberal trade did
not figure on the Uruguay Round agenda.
Tariffs
Despite its lack of teeth, the old GATT system played a central role in reducing
tariffs, the main form of protectionism during the inter-war period. In 1947, the average
tariff on manufactured trade was 47 per cent; by 1980, following successive rounds of
trade negotiations, it had fallen to 6 per cent. Full implementation of the Uruguay Round
agreement will further reduce the average industrial-country tariff to 3.9 per cent (GATT
1994).
Disaggregating this average figure makes it clear that the benefits will be biased
towards the developed countries and South Asia. Thus the average tariff reduction for
trade among industrialised countries is higher (45 per cent) than the overall average (38
per cent) for developed-country tariff cuts (Woodward, 1996). For imports from Asia, the
average tariff reduction is about one third, compared with 20-25 per cent for other
developing regions. Tariff concessions between the developed countries are also more
extensive with regard to tariff peaks. Thus the share of imports from all sources paying
tariffs in excess of 10 per cent will fall from 15 per cent to 10 per cent for all
countries; but only from 21 per cent to 15 per cent for developing countries (Weston,
1994).
Paradoxically, the smallest tariff reductions have been adopted for the poorest
countries. With the full implementation of the Uruguay Round, the average tariff on
imports from the least-developed countries into the developed countries will be 30 per
cent higher than the overall average. For developing countries as a group, it will be 10
per cent higher. This reflects the lower reductions applied to products of greatest
interest to the world's poorest countries (Safadi and Yeats, 1996). Tariff rates in the
four major developed-country markets after the Uruguay Round tariff reductions are
implemented will remain considerably above the average for agricultural goods, textiles,
leather, and footwear - all areas in which developing countries have a major interest.
Another problem is tariff escalation: the practice of setting higher tariffs on
processed goods than on raw materials (see Safadi and Yeats 1993). This obstructs an
obvious way for developing countries to add value to their exports: namely, by processing
raw materials before they sell them. The impact of tariff escalation is to deter
investment, undermine employment, and lock developing countries into volatile
primary-commodity markets, where real prices are in secular decline. In general terms,
tariff escalation will be reduced under the Uruguay Round agreement. But it remains
important in a number of key sectors. For some commodities of major significance to
developing countries - such as leather, oilseeds, textile fibres and beverages - tariffs
will continue to escalate by between 8 and 26 per cent on the final-stage product (World
Bank, 1994b). While tariff escalation may not be the principal barrier to developing
countries expanding the domestic value-added of their exports, this structure will
inevitably discourage exports and restrict foreign-exchange earnings (UNCTAD 1994).
Non-tariff barriers
As tariff barriers declined under successive GATT agreements, industrial countries
increasingly resorted to non-tariff barriers (NTBs) as the preferred means of restricting
imports, especially from developing countries. The Multi-Fibre Arrangement (MFA), which is
considered below, was one variant. Other measures included the euphemistically title
'voluntary export restraints' (VERs), under which countries were invited to limit exports
or face retaliatory trade restriction, safeguards, and anti-dumping duties.
Under the Uruguay Round agreement, new rules have been adopted to reduce the incidence
of NTBs. Developing countries stand to make significant gains, since NTBs have been
applied disproportionately to products - such as steel, footwear, textiles, leather and
rubber goods - in which they have a major interest. The coverage of developing-country
exports is scheduled to decline from 18 per cent to 5.5 per cent (Woodward, 1994).
That said, the scope for evasion of the spirit, if not the letter, of the Final Act
remains considerable. VERs are to be phased out over a four-year period. However, the
picture with regard to safeguards is more confused. One of the reasons why developed
countries have resorted so heavily to safeguard actions is that they can be applied
selectively (unlike Article XIX actions) and without compensation. The EU had wanted this
departure from GATT principles enshrined in the WTO. That outcome was avoided. However,
selective safeguards may still be applied, albeit with a four-year time ceiling and with
evidence of actual injury, against suppliers whose exports to a market grow
'disproportionately'. General safeguards may also be applied for longer periods, to
prevent serious injury. Both provisions suggest that considerable scope for the harassment
of exporters has been retained. Another danger is that safeguards will replace VERs as the
main vehicle for discriminatory protectionism.
The same is true of anti-dumping actions. These have been widely applied by the US and
the EU against developing-country exports of everything from steel to colour televisions
and toys. Under the GATT, importers used a wide variety of anti-dumping formulas in
adjudication procedures. However, they shared in common mechanisms designed to guarantee a
high degree of success for the domestic industries bringing complaints. Under the old EU
system, the level of success in prosecuting anti-dumping actions was unmatched in any
other area of judicial action (Hindley 1989). Under the new system, more uniform rules
have been adopted. The problem is that these rules retain some highly arbitrary criteria:
for instance, in estimating reasonable profit against which to measure dumping margins. On
the other side of the balance sheet, smaller developing countries will benefit from the
provision exempting from anti-dumping action countries supplying less than 3 per cent of
the market (UNCTAD, 1994). Beyond this there are no special provisions for developing
countries. In view of the considerable costs and technical demands facing any country
wishing to context an anti-dumping action, this is a serious shortcoming.
It is too early to evaluate the overall agreement on NTBs. However, close monitoring is
required to ensure that the developed countries comply with the spirit of the Final Act.
As in other areas of international trade, the only real defence against unfair recourse to
NTBs is retaliatory action - and this is an area in which developing countries have
unequal leverage.
Special and differential treatment
For practical purposes, the special and differential (S&D) provisions applied under
Part IV of the GATT for developing countries brought few benefits. In theory, Part IV
provided developing countries with an opportunity to benefit from global liberalisation
without corresponding obligations. In practice, recourse to S&D, arguments resulted in
developing countries being marginalised in successive multilateral trade rounds, with
developed countries having no immediate self-interest in opening their markets on a
non-reciprocal basis. Instead, developed countries were able to use their influence over
the IMF and World Bank to secure the liberalisation measures which they would otherwise
have been required to negotiate under the GATT. In the run-up to the Uruguay Round,
developing countries themselves were less strident in their defence of S&D, which was
widely perceived as a failed policy option. For their part, the developed countries saw
the Round as an opportunity to further dilute Part IV provisions. The upshot is that,
while the overall language of the Final Act uses the old language of S&D - i.e.
developing countries are expected to make concessions consistent with their development,
financial, and trade needs - the concept has been seriously eroded. What does this mean in
practice?
One important implication is that developing countries have lost some flexibility in
using trade-policy measures for balance-of-payments purposes. In particular, their ability
to resort to quantitative restrictions on imports has been severely curtailed. Developing
countries have also accepted tariff binding, albeit at levels significantly above
currently applied rates. Ironically, developing countries now have less scope for
resorting to quantitative restrictions than developed countries, which have retained the
right to use them under the agreements for agriculture, textiles, and safeguards.
It is a similar situation with regard to subsidies, where the agreement is tailored to
the requirements of developed countries. Thus subsidies are prohibited for product
development (which is vital for many developing countries), but permitted for research and
development and labour retraining, which are more relevant to developed countries. In the
case of agriculture (see below), the subsidy rules have been contrived to allow the
developed countries to maintain transfers to farmers through direct budgetary payments,
while restricting market-based transfers. That approach may be viable in a situation where
budget resources are large relative to the size of the agricultural population. But for
developing countries, where the rural sector typically accounts for over half of all
employment, and where governments face serious budgetary constraints, it is not an option.
In most areas of the Final Act, S&D treatment means that developing countries are
given longer time-frames in which to implement more modest commitments to liberalisation.
Thus in the case of agriculture, developing countries have ten years (rather than six) in
which to reduce import tariffs by 24 per cent (rather than 36 per cent). The underlying
logic of obliging developing countries to reduce restrictions on imports in markets
dominated by the industrialised countries, where subsidised transfers to farmers represent
half the value of agricultural output, is questioned below.
For developing countries, intellectual property rights are another significant aspect
of the Uruguay Round agreement. Essentially, the Final Act requires the extension to
twenty years of effective patent protection for all areas of technology recognised in the
developed countries. The act also extends the scope of intellectual-property protection by
limiting exclusions. Differential treatment, as it has been elaborated under the Final
Act, will allow developing countries longer time-frames for implementation (with five-and
ten-year grace periods respectively for developing and least-developed countries). One of
the most important effects will be to increase the cost of imported technologies on which
competitiveness in international markets depends. This will generate windfall gains for
the owners of patents - notably US, European, and Japanese TNCs - while imposing new
foreign-exchange demands on the poorest countries. Yet there is no provision to compensate
developing countries for these additional costs.
More generally, intellectual property rights remain an area of international trade
characterised by deeply rooted double standards. In the early phases of its industrial
development, the USA adapted and developed European technologies without regard for patent
rights. Japan followed this example after World War II. Today, however, developing
countries are having their right to adapt technologies curtailed by these same countries.
In contrast to other areas of international trade, where 'free trade' is the dominant
ethos, in intellectual property the industrialised countries are adopting overtly
trade-restricting practices as a means of enhancing rent transfers to transnational
companies, which account for an estimated 90 per cent of patents (Gibb, 1988).
Textiles and clothing
Until the Uruguay Round, the textiles and clothing sector - along with agriculture -
was the major exception in the movement towards freer trade. Managed trade in textiles
began in 1961 and evolved through four successive versions of the Multifibre Arrangement
(MFA). Initially, the move was justified as a temporary arrangement, under which
industries in the developed world would be given time to adjust. The 'temporary'
arrangement survived for three decades. Though posing as a multilateral system, the MFA
was in reality a complex package of bilateral arrangements under which the industrialised
countries fixed quotas on a country-by-country and product-by-product basis. In each
succeeding phase, the MFA became either wider ranging (by covering more products) or more
restrictive (by imposing tighter quotas) - or, more usually, both.
The costs of the MFA have been exceptionally high in the developing world. Textile and
clothing figure prominently in the manufactured exports of all developing regions,
accounting for 24 per cent of the total for Africa, 14 per cent for Asia, and 8 per cent
for Latin America (Majumdar, 1995). For some of the poorest countries, textiles and
clothing are the most important source of foreign-exchange earnings. For example, both
Bangladesh and Sri Lanka depend on the sector for around half of their total export
earnings. Estimates of the total foreign-exchange losses resulting from MFA quotas and
tariffs range from $4bn to $15bn annually (the most widely used estimates are Trela and
Whalley 1990; and Yang 1994). These losses are transmitted through the mechanisms of
international trade to local industries in the form of lower wages, reduced employment,
and lower investment, all of which have adverse implications for poverty reduction (Cable
V 1990).
The delayed 'phase-out'
To what extent will the Uruguay Round Agreement on Textiles and Clothing (ATC) resolve
the problems faced by developing-country exporters? In principle, the ATC provides a legal
framework for integrating the sector into normal WTO disciplines over a ten-year
transition period. Thus developed countries have granted themselves the same special and
differential terms in textiles as they have extended to developing countries under the
agricultural agreement! The phasing out of MFA restrictions comprises two strands: the
elimination of restrictions in bilateral agreements negotiated under the MFA umbrella, and
an increase in quotas according to a fixed growth rate. There are three steps in this
process. In 1995, importing countries were required to remove from MFA restriction 16 per
cent of textiles and clothing imports; in 1998, they are required to remove a further 17
per cent; and in 2002 another 18 per cent. In 2005, all remaining products are to be
integrated. There are parallel arrangements for increasing growth rates for quotas (Trela
I 1995).
There are two points to be made about this arrangement. First, tariffs will remain very
high in the textiles and clothing sector. At 12 per cent, the average tariff will be three
times the industrial-country average, implying a high degree of discrimination against
developing- country suppliers. Second, the industrial countries appear to have adopted a
policy of implementing the letter of the ATC, while violating its spirit. This applies per
force to the US and the EU, despite wider differences in their policy approaches.
The USA
In contrast to the EU, the USA has published a full list of products to be phased out
over the different stages to the year 2005 (Majumdar 1995). Most sensitive products will
remain on the MFA list until the very end. This applies to 14 product categories exported
by Bangladesh, 21 exported by Thailand, and 27 exported by the Philippines. The US has
also exploited a wide range of loopholes to restrict import growth. Within a few months of
the agreement being put into place, it had instituted 25 'safeguard' applications to the
WTO, five of them against Honduras, and three against India (WTO 1996). Eleven of these
resulted in restraint measures being adopted, five on a unilateral basis without approval
by the WTO. In another worrying development, rules-of-origin provisions are being applied
with increasing inflexibility, for instance by restricting imports of table cloths
produced in the Philippines with fabrics imported from China or Thailand (Far Eastern
Economic Review 1996). These measures have attracted criticism from Pakistan and the ASEAN
countries, which are pressing for a review of the ATC.
The EU
The EU has adopted a different approach, linking implementation of the ATC to improved
access to developing-country markets. Countries such as India have been invited to reduce
their tariffs on EU clothing and textile imports, in return for concessions in the EU
market. The issue has emerged as a source of tension between the EU and around a dozen of
its Asian trade partners, point out that they are under no legal obligation to offer
reciprocal tariff reductions. More broadly, there is something inherently questionable in
principle about the developed countries demanding that the developing countries bargain
for the withdrawal of trade restrictions which were themselves a violation of GATT
principles.
The EU has also hit upon the ingenious idea of including in the first phase of
'liberalisation' items - such as parachutes and car-seat belts - not previously covered by
the MFA. Almost 60 per cent of all the items offered for liberalisation by the EU fall
into this category, thereby minimising the benefits to developing country exporters.
Meanwhile, trade in clothing, which is the most important export for the poorest
countries, has been the least integrated into the EU's liberalisation plans, accounting
for just 2 per cent of the total product coverage. Items are also categorised by their
'sensitivity', with restrictions being retained for products likely to compete with
domestic industries. One of the worst-affected countries is Vietnam, which has 27 clothing
products under restriction, most of which are confined to growth rates of less than 2 per
cent.
To be fair to the EU, it has not been alone in its efforts to flout the ATC. In October
1996, the Textiles Monitoring Body of the WTO evaluated the liberalisation measures
undertaken by importing countries under the first phase of the agreement. It concluded
that, with the exception of one product in one country (gloves in Canada), none of the
items subject to liberalisation was subject to quantitative restrictions prior to 1994.
The report also noted that the products in question were in the relatively lower
value-added range, suggesting that the requirement that import volumes be increased by 16
per cent was being met in a way which secured far lower benefits expressed in value terms.
'End-loading'
It is difficult to escape the conclusion that the primary concern of the EU and the US
has been to restrict imports in the interests of protecting domestic employment. The
danger is that, by 'end-loading' the transfer of benefits to developing countries, both
the US and the EU have, in the eyes of exporting countries, created a breathing space for
protectionist lobbies to achieve a postponement of the final stage of the ATC. As the
International Textile and Clothing Bureau has put it: "The notifications (by the EU
and the USA) do not demonstrate political will...to integrate textiles and clothing into
the liberalisation of trade" (DiDonato, 1995). Domestic political pressures - and
social problems - provide part of the explanation for this lack of political will. In
parts of the EU - notably Britain - and in the USA, the textile sector is characterised by
low wages and declining employment levels (with the number of jobs declining by around 3
per cent a year for the past decade). That said, there is surely a case for governments to
adopt more active labour-retraining and skills-enhancement programmes as an alternative to
imposing adjustment costs on developing countries.
Partial losers
Viewed from the perspective of some of the poorest countries, liberalisation of the
textile and clothing sector poses problems of a different order. In a liberalised trade
environment, the most competitive countries are likely to gain most, with China,
Indonesia, Thailand, and South Asia figuring prominently (World Bank, 1996; Page and
Davenport, 1994). By contrast, exporters with large quotas relative to their
competitiveness will lose out, unless they are able to raise productivity, as will
countries which are currently insulated from competition by quotas on more competitive
suppliers. In this group, Nepal, Bangladesh, and Sri Lanka stand to lose out. According to
one estimate, Bangladesh could suffer a decline of almost one fifth in export earnings
(Page and Davenport, 1994). This would have disastrous implications for human welfare.
Around one million people are employed in the Bangladeshi garment industry, 90 per cent of
whom are women (Ahmad and Kabir, 1995). While conditions in the textile industry are
characterised by low pay and poor conditions, there are few alternative sources of
employment. Women workers in the textile industry are often the main household income
earners, supporting large numbers of dependants. For many, the loss of livelihoods in the
textile industry would be a one-way ticket to increased poverty and vulnerability.
Agriculture and food security
From the outset, agricultural trade was effectively excluded from the rules of the
GATT. Initially, this was because the US refused to accept multilateral disciplines to
regulate its right to restrict imports and subsidise exports. The EU was subsequently able
to exploit GATT's weak agricultural provisions, which were sufficiently flexible to
incorporate its Common Agricultural Policy (CAP). The Agreement on Agriculture adopted at
the Uruguay Round marks the first step towards the incorporation of agriculture into the
multilateral trading system. However, that step is a very tentative one, and the balance
of responsibilities and obligations between developed and developing countries is highly
uneven.
The impact of Northern subsidies
Agricultural subsidisation, over-production, and export dumping by the industrialised
countries have been the most visible manifestations of the special status of agriculture
in world trade. Developing countries have suffered foreign-exchange losses as a
consequence of the lower world prices and lost market shares resulting from competition
against subsidised exports. Such losses are inherently difficult to quantify. However, one
estimate suggests that a 30 per cent reduction in subsidies and protection would increase
developing-country export earnings by around $45bn (Goldin and van der Mensbrugghe, 1993).
The major beneficiaries would be a core group of Asian (Thailand, Malaysia and Indonesia)
and Latin American (Brazil, Argentina and Uruguay) exporters of temperate products such as
cereals, oilseeds and meat and livestock. During the 1980s, these exporters suffered
unprecedented losses as export dumping by the EU and the USA drove prices down to their
lowest levels since the 1930s, with developing countries caught in the cross-fire of a
subsidy war.
As a group, developing countries have progressively lost agricultural market-shares to
the developed countries over the past four decades. In 1950, they accounted for around one
half of world agricultural trade. Today, they account for one quarter (FAO 1996b).
Paradoxically, the countries which depend least upon agricultural trade as a source of
foreign exchange, employment, and income have been expanding their market domination. For
instance, the EU was barely self-sufficient in sugar less than two decades ago, but is now
the world's largest exporter of sugar. Conversely, the countries which are most dependent
on agriculture for their social and economic development have been losing out.
It is not only agricultural exporters that have faced problems. Staple-food producers
in many developing countries have been forced to compete in local markets against heavily
subsidised imports. These imports have depressed domestic prices and created consumer
demand for foodstuffs which are not produced locally. The displacement of cassava,
sorghum, and millet by wheat-based bread and imported rice in West Africa is an example of
this process (Reardon, 1994). Cereals imports now absorb around one quarter of sub-Saharan
Africa's export earnings. In many of the poorest countries, dependence upon food imports
is increasing as per capita food-production declines, partly as a consequence of the
market effects of food-dumping. Even in Latin America and the Caribbean, per capita
cereals production was lower in 1990 than in 1960 (FAO, 1996a).
Food-security issues
Cheap food imports have positive short-term income benefits for food-deficit countries
and households. At a national level, subsidised dumping by the industrialised countries
reduces the foreign-exchange costs of imports. For governments pursuing industrial
development strategies based upon cheap food, the advantages are obvious. They help to
explain why some developing countries attached such importance to securing compensation
for the Uruguay Round agreement, claiming that it would increase their food-import costs.
For the poorest households, which spend the largest proportion of their income on food,
this is an important consideration. In many developing countries, urban populations are
critically dependent upon imported foodstuffs. But the poorest rural households are also
typically in a food-deficit situation, selling crops in the post-harvest period and
purchasing staples after household supplies have run out (Mellor, 1995). In narrowly
defined income terms, these households stand to benefit from any reduction in local prices
caused by imports - and, by extension, from subsidised food-dumping.
The problem is that food-security problems cannot be viewed solely in narrowly-defined
income terms. At a national level, many of the 88 countries categorised by the FAO as
low-income food-deficit are not in a position to sustain imports (FAO 1996a). Nor can they
rely upon food aid to cover shortfalls. The hike in world prices during 1995 added some
$4bn to the import bills of these countries, while food shortages fell to their lowest
levels since the mid-1970s. Food- deficit countries in sub-Saharan Africa, faced as they
are with deep-rooted problems of debt and dependence upon volatile commodity markets, are
not in the same position as South Korea when it comes to ensuring that food imports can be
secured whenever, and in whatever quantities, they may be needed. That is why the Economic
Commission for Africa has stressed that "Africa's viability resides, above all other
considerations, in its being able to feed its own people from internal resources"
(Economic Commission for Africa, 1991).
It is also questionable whether expenditure on food imports constitutes the most
productive use of one of the scarcest resources of low-income countries namely, their
foreign exchange. Collectively, the FAO's eighty-eight low-income food-deficit countries
spend half of their foreign exchange on food imports. Yet in many of these countries,
smallholder farmers are more than capable of feeding their countries. What is needed is
the creation by governments of an enabling environment which facilitates the participation
in markets of poor producers and more marginal areas. Public investment in infrastructure,
marketing, and post-harvest facilities, allied to agrarian reform and tenancy legislation
aimed at enhancing access to land, water and other productive assets, is vital to the
creation of such an environment. Action in this area should not be viewed as part of a
trade-off between growth and poverty reduction. Given an opportunity, smallholder
producers are highly productive (IFAD, 1990), and increased rural prosperity can provide
the foundation for dynamic urban-rural economic linkages. Unfortunately, governments in
many developing countries are unlikely to undertake the investments needed in smallholder
production while the industrialised countries are offering apparently limitless supplies
of 'cheap food'.
All change and no change in OECD subsidisation
Against this backdrop, the Uruguay Round agreement needs to be evaluated against one
central criterion: will it end subsidised over-production and food-dumping by the
industrialised countries? The answer is 'no'.
Briefly summarised, the Agricultural Agreement envisages a 36 per cent reduction in
spending on production and export subsidies (with the volume of subsidised exports falling
by 21 per cent), and a similar level of tariff reduction. All non-tariff measures are to
be 'tariffied'. While superficially impressive, the real effects of these measures will be
limited. For instance, the subsidy reduction applies only to measures which 'distort'
trade. Direct payments to farmers, as distinct from market-support measures, are not
included in this category, largely as a result of a bilateral agreement between the US and
the EU. These payments currently account for almost one quarter of total OECD
subsidisation. Moreover, the proportion is rising, as governments restructure their
subsidy programmes to bring them into line with the WTO regime. Another limiting factor is
the choice of 1986-1988 as the reference period against which to measure budget-spending
reductions. Subsidies during this period were the highest ever, thus minimising the need
for liberalisation. The end result is that the $182bn in producer subsidies provided by
the OECD countries in 1995 - a sum representing 40 per cent of the value of output - is
unlikely to decline (OECD 1996). It is worth mentioning that the 1995 subsidy figure was
some 15 per cent higher than that at the start of the Uruguay Round.
The position in relation to export subsidies is similar. The reference period from
which reductions will be measured (either 1986-1990 or 1990-1991) has been chosen to
increase the level of export subsidisation which is permissible, in the case of the EU by
around by around 10m tons of cereal. Moreover, the 21 per cent reduction in the volume of
subsidised exports which are acceptable will leave the other 79 per cent untouched - an
obvious point, but one which has received surprisingly little attention (Fowler P 1996;
Gardner B 1993). The upshot is that agriculture will remain the one area of international
trade under which multilateral trade rules sanction and institutionalise export-dumping.
Turning to the question of tariff reductions, the 1986-1990 reference period again
means that real reductions will be substantially lower than the headline figure suggests.
Equivalent reductions from current levels would create double the level of welfare gains,
according to the World Bank's estimate (World Bank 1995). Moreover, the industrialised
countries appear to have used baseline figures even higher than the 1986-1990 average for
a number of major commodities, with the result that actual tariffs are now higher than
they were (Stevens, 1996).
It is difficult to escape the conclusion that the US and the EU have written the
Agricultural Agreement to legitimise, under WTO auspices, their various subsidy
operations. In any area of world trade, this subordination of multilateralism to the
pursuit of self-interest ought to be regarded as unacceptable. In the specific case of
agriculture, which is of such vital importance to the world's poorest countries, the case
for a fundamental review is overwhelming. That case is reinforced by the fact that the
Agricultural Agreement requires developing countries to reduce the level of import
protection to their food-staple producers - in effect, exposing them to global markets
distorted by US and EU subsidies (Oxfam, 1996). This would appear to be a violation of the
very market principles upon which the WTO is founded. More importantly, unequal
competition in global markets between smallholder producers in the South and the
industrialised farming systems and treasuries of the North poses a major threat to rural
livelihoods and human development.
The distribution of benefits
There has been a wide range of assessments of the overall income effects of the Uruguay
Round. The increase in global income expected to result from liberalisation is variously
estimated at between $212bn and $510bn (World Bank/OECD 1993; Nguyen et al, 1994; Francois
et al, 1994). Developing countries are projected to gain between $86bn and $122bn. These
wide variations reflect differences in methodology (for example, the higher estimates tend
to reflect assumptions about efficiency-related productivity gains), the inclusion or
otherwise of non-tariff barriers, elasticities in supply, and other factors.
In reality, these figures provide more of an insight into the underlying conviction
shared by most economists, that freer trade is good for growth, than they do about likely
outcomes in the real world. That said, the various econometric evaluations of the Uruguay
Round raise some important questions about distribution. For instance, most studies
suggest that developing countries, which collectively account for around three quarters of
the world's population, will account for only between one quarter and one third of the
income gains generated: hardly an equitable outcome.
This may well understate the problem, since the most significant gains, amounting to 60
per cent, 34 per cent, and 20 per cent respectively (World Bank 1994b), are predicted for
clothing (where liberalisation is likely to remain on the back burner for another decade),
textiles (where current trends suggest a serious lag in implementation), and agriculture
(where the benefits of the Uruguay Round agreement have been massively overstated).
However, with all their limitations, the more optimistic figures mentioned above speak
volumes about the unbalanced nature of the Uruguay Round agenda and it is bias towards the
interests of industrialised countries. It also suggests that the Uruguay Round will
further skew the distribution of global wealth in favour of the world's richest countries.
It is only North-South patterns of income distribution which will become more unequal
as a result of the Uruguay Round. Within the developing world, the benefits of trade
liberalisation will be unequally distributed between the larger, more advanced exporters
of manufacturing goods in south-east Asia and Latin America and the poorer
primary-commodity producers in Africa and elsewhere. Most studies suggest that the very
poorest countries stand to lose from the Uruguay Round agreement, especially in the short
run. This group includes countries which are beneficiaries of various preferential tariff
schemes - such as the Lome Convention - which will face increased competition as a
consequence of liberalisation. Preferences for the African, Caribbean, and Pacific (ACP)
countries in the EU market will be eroded by some 30 per cent as a result of
liberalisation under the Uruguay Round, and by 50 per cent for tropical products. One
study (Page and Davenport 1994) estimates that Ethiopia, Malawi and Mozambique, three of
the poorest countries in the world, will suffer export losses in excess of 4 per cent per
annum as a consequence of preference erosion. Similarly, while developing countries as a
group are projected to gain from liberalisation in clothing and textiles, the ACP and
least-developed countries are projected to lose from the loss of preference margins.
Bangladesh and Mauritius stand to be particularly affected.
Since Most Favoured Nation (MFN) tariffs are being reduced at twice the rate of
Generalised System of Preference (GSP) tariffs, the wider preferences enjoyed by
least-developed countries also stand to be eroded. While it is true that the GSP may have
yielded limited results, its erosion could carry significant costs for some countries
(Stevens and Kennan, 1994). According to UNCTAD, the least-developed countries stand to
lose up to $600m annually - a sum equivalent to around 5 per cent of their export earnings
(Weston, 1994).
The generalised conviction that trade liberalisation will ultimately benefit all
countries has obscured a more complex balance-sheet of winners and losers. At a global
level, the projected losses are small and heavily outweighed by overall income gains. Even
so, the losses will be concentrated on a group of countries that can least afford them -
and for some the costs will be significant. This scenario has disturbing implications for
poverty and human welfare. Foreign-exchange losses will translate into pressure on
incomes, a declining inability to sustain imports, and increased dependence upon aid.
Revenue from trade will be lost, undermining the capacity of governments to develop the
economic and social infrastructures upon which future prosperity depends. Thus, apart from
widening the income gap between the world's poorest and the more dynamic developing
countries in the short-term, the Uruguay Round agreement could initiate a longer-term
trend towards increased inequality.
Policy considerations: a post-Uruguay Round agenda
While the Uruguay Round agreement poses a number of potential threats to some of the
poorest countries, it also has the potential to generate income gains for others. Perhaps
most importantly, a strengthened WTO may limit the recourse of the developed countries to
the type of arbitrary and discriminatory trade policies which characterised the 1980s. As
the weakest partners in the international trading system, developing countries as a group
have the most limited retaliatory capacity, and are therefore most vulnerable to
departures from a rules-based system. Against this, the industrialised countries have
clearly not abandoned unilateralism. The Helms-Burton Act in the US not only reinforces
sanctions against Cuba, it also extends sanctions to other countries which refuse to
comply with US edicts. As such, the Act is a blatant departure from multilateral trade
disciplines. So, too, is the continued recourse by the US to the threat of trade sanctions
under Section 301 of the Trade Act. This entitles the US Trade Representative to impose
sanctions against countries deemed to be pursuing 'unfair' trade practices. Significantly,
it has been most heavily deployed in areas - such as the enforcement of patent claims and
the pursuit of initiatives to open investment markets - in which the Uruguay Round
agreement is regarded by the USA as inadequate, with developing countries among the most
prominent targets. As the case of textiles illustrates, the scope for arbitrary
protectionism also remains intact.
If multilateralism is to flourish, and if the poorest developing countries are to
participate more fully and equitably in the international trading system, major reforms
are needed. There have been some positive developments, both the US and the EU are
considering reforms of their Generalised System of Preference schemes, reducing the per
capita income threshold for eligibility and the upper ceiling on market shares after which
preferences will be withdrawn (Weston, 1994). Reinforced preferences could help to redress
losses suffered by the poorest countries as a consequence of Most Favoured Nation
liberalisation under the Uruguay Round. However, the utilisation and benefits of GSP
schemes for the poorest countries have been limited, and the share of preferential imports
in dutiable imports has been declining (UNCTAD 1993). In 1994, UNCTAD's Special Committee
on Preferences concluded that, apart from the weak supply-capacity of the poorest
countries, GSP schemes were limited by factors such as their incomplete product-coverage,
with the exclusion of 'sensitive' items in agriculture a special problem; the imposition
of quota constraints on duty-free imports; complex rules-of-origin criteria which set
upper limits on the proportion of value-added to exports by imported inputs; and by
uncertainties surrounding the continuation of preferences, which limited an investment
response. In each of these areas there is scope for accelerated liberalisation.
The WTO
One way in which developed countries could assist the poorest countries would be to
conduct a review of the rules-of-origins arrangements with a view to simplifying the
rules, and increasing - or, perhaps, removing - the ceilings for import-content. At the
same time, GSP arrangements could be restructured, with exports produced by countries -
such as the African, Caribbean and Pacific group under Lome - suffering preference losses
as a result of liberalisation under the WTO being given special preferences. These options
are considered in the Comprehensive and Integrated WTO Plan of Action for the LDCs, which
calls for a comprehensive approach to "contribute to the expansion of trade,
sustainable growth and development" of the poorest countries (WTO, 1996). But no
detailed recommendations have been adopted or implemented.
More concrete and substantive action is required for LDCs (see, for example, UNCTAD
1995). This should include:
- the elimination of tariff escalation, especially in GSP schemes for
semi-processed tropical agricultural produce and natural resources;
- deeper tariff cuts and duty elimination under GSP and other preferential
schemes still subject to high tariff peaks;
- more flexible and consistent rules of origin aimed at promoting
labour-intensive exports;
- exemptions from restrictions on textile imports for small suppliers, regardless
of whether or not they are WTO members;
- a prohibition on safeguard actions against products exported by LDCs.
With regard to imports, it is important that the special and differential provisions of
the Uruguay Round are respected. 'Graduation' into full WTO obligations must take into
account the specific circumstances of individual countries and economic sectors, with the
objective of giving precedence to poverty reduction considerations over the claims of
developed countries for access to markets. In this respect, the EU's approach to the
implementation of the ATC is a major source of concern, since it appears that special and
differential treatment is regarded as a trade barrier, rather than a legitimate claim. In
the specific case of agriculture, there should be no obligation on developing countries to
open up their food systems, because international markets are massively distorted by OECD
subsidisation; and because the food security of people should take precedence over any
requirement to liberalise.
Finally, there are important institutional questions which need to be addressed if the
poorest countries are to participate in the WTO on more equitable terms. At present, there
are 29 LDC members of the WTO. Only nine of these countries maintain a trade
representative's office in Geneva. Even those countries which do maintain offices are
massively over-stretched. While the US and the EU are able to mobilise and maintain armies
of trade lawyers, technical specialists (often seconded from transnational companies), and
official negotiators, most developing countries have one or two officials available.
During the Uruguay Round, these officials were covering fifteen different negotiating
areas, ranging from textiles to intellectual property and investment, while the developed
countries were able to deploy entire teams for each working group. Such asymmetries in
negotiating strength have obvious implications for the outcome of bargaining processes.
Increased co-operation between developing countries, allied to shared specialisation, is
part of the answer; but increased financial and technical support should also be made
available through the WTO itself to create a more democratic structure.
The European Union
The European Union has special obligations to the poorest countries - and an important
opportunity to meet them. Since the mid-1970s, the core of EU development policy has been
the Lome Convention - an aid and trade preference arrangement linking it to 70 African,
Caribbean and Pacific (ACP) countries. With the current convention due to expire in 2000,
new policy directions are under consideration (European Union 1996). The outcome is a
matter of vital concern to some of the world's poorest countries. Not only is the EU a
major source of aid to the ACP countries, it also absorbs more than 40 per cent of their
exports. Among these countries, there is a high concentration of those which have suffered
an erosion of preferences because of the Uruguay Round agreement.
In many respects, the concrete achievements of the Lome Convention have been limited.
Even with preferential access to the EU market, the ACP countries have failed to
diversify, with over 80 per cent of their export earnings coming from primary commodities.
They have also been unable to maintain their share of the EU market, which has fallen from
7 per cent in 1976 to 3 per cent today. Such facts have reinforced a growing conviction in
the EU that existing Lome trade policies have failed - but the alternatives which are
emerging are far from convincing.
One option under review is a modified status quo, with the EU maintaining a WTO
'waiver' for ACP preferences. Given past performance, this is not an attractive option.
Another approach, favoured by some EU governments, is to focus upon reciprocal trade
liberalisation, with the ACP countries taking on liberalisation obligations consistent
with their development status. In effect, this would make the Lome Convention, at present
a non-reciprocal contractual arrangement, an extension of the WTO, requiring the full
integration of the ACP countries into the multilateral trade framework. A third option
under review is the removal of the trade element from the Lome Convention (which would
thus be reduced to an aid package), and its integration into the EU's GSP scheme for
least-developed countries. The problem with this is that the EU's GSP scheme has been even
less successful than the Lome Convention in improving the capacity of the poorest
countries to take advantage of opportunities in the EU market.
What is needed is a more integrated approach, in which EU development cooperation
policy is geared towards expanding market opportunities, and increasing the capacity of
the poorest countries to take advantage of those opportunities. The first part of this
equation requires a fundamental review of existing trade restrictions applied to the
least-developed countries. Restrictions under the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) and the
enforcement of arcane rules of origin are two obvious areas for reform. The second part of
the equation requires a closer co-ordination of aid and trade, with the EU gearing its aid
policy more effectively towards the promotion of investment, production, and local
processing in areas where it is providing trade advantages.
Another area in which the EU faces a major challenge is with regard to
the special protocols attached to the Lome Convention. These protocols, which extend to
sugar, beef, rum, and bananas, give individual ACP countries privileged access to the EU
market in the form of quotas and higher prices. The banana protocol, upon which the
survival of thousands of livelihoods in the Windward Islands and other Caribbean countries
depends, has been successfully challenged at the WTO by the USA, acting on behalf of
American transnational companies exporting from Latin America. Under the WTO ruling, the
EU regime was found to be discriminatory and a barrier to free trade. At one level, that
assessment was correct. At another level it has to be asked whether the livelihoods of
entire communities should be sacrificed in the commercial interest of powerful TNCs.
NEXT SECTION
UNDP Home
BACK TO TOP
|