|
III. VARIOUS ACTORS IN THE SHRIMP INDUSTRY Most of the literature on shrimp aquaculture is relatively uncritical
concerning its social impacts. One reason for this neglect is because its authors seldom
distinguish between the different actors who are involved and affected. This section
attempts to identify the principal actors throughout the shrimp production chain from the
producer up to the consumer, including official agencies and lending institutions. Section
IV will focus on actors who are not included in the industry, but are negatively affected
by externalities and by reduced access to natural resources.
Commercial shrimp aquaculture is considered to be an industry because it
integrates the whole production chain of which the cultivation stage is only the first
link. It also involves many inputs and technologies which are produced by other
industries. The industries producing the inputs and aquaculture technologies and those
which are processing and marketing the product employ many more workers than does
production at the farm level.
Commercial aquaculture combines many elements from fisheries and
agriculture. Aquaculture, in contrast to the fishing industry, has no professional
identity. As a result it has received little attention by national and international
labour organizations. In Ecuador, which has been among the leading exporters of shrimp for
over a decade, efforts to organize labour unions by shrimp industry workers have been
consistently broken (Snedaker et al., 1986). The International Labour Organization has no
data on employment in shrimp aquaculture. Some Asian governmental agency and FAO reports
give crude estimates of overall employment in aquaculture. There is almost no information
breaking down employment according to the different labour categories at each level of
shrimp production. Consequently, we have to make inferences based on fragmentary data
taken from somewhat non-comparable Asian country reports.
Shrimp Farmers And Labourers
There is apparently an average of one to three persons working on a
full-time basis per hectare of semi-intensive and intensive shrimp pond and up to seven
for extensive ponds. Worldwide, shrimp farms covered approximately 962,600 hectares in
1993 and may have employed the full-time equivalent of over one million workers.[10] This farm level employment includes temporary
low-paid construction workers and permanent maintenance labourers (handling, pumping,
feeding, pond water treatment and harvesting), supervisors, and guards to prevent the
theft of shrimp from the grow-out ponds. A few temporary employment opportunities are
given to engineers, heavy equipment operators, researchers and consultants. In East Java
and Viet Nam employment costs have been estimated to be about 6 per cent of total
operating costs in intensive shrimp farming (Chong, 1992) compared with about 30 to 40 per
cent in traditional extensive shrimp production (Kongkeo, 1990). With the tendency to
develop more semi-intensive and intensive modes of shrimp production, labour as a portion
of total costs is being reduced by using more energy and technical inputs.
"Aquaculture (shrimp) can hardly be regarded as a mass employer" (Ben-Yami,
1986).
Compared to other production systems taking place in the same coastal
areas mostly rice production labour requirements for shrimp aquaculture are
very low. One study in Indonesia reports that rice production employed an average of 76
workdays per hectare per crop cycle. In the same area, a semi-intensive shrimp farm
employed about 26 workdays per hectare (McCoy, cited in Bailey and Skladany, 1991), and an
extensive shrimp farm about 45 workdays per hectare per cycle (Hanning, 1988). Extensive
shrimp production in West Bengal, on 100 bighas[11],
was reported to employ about one third less labour than when the same area was used for
rice paddy. In West Bengal, extensive shrimp production, called Jalkar, lasts seven
to eight months per year, after which rice paddy cultivation takes over for the remaining
months of the year. In this case, labour costs amount to about 7 per cent of the shrimp
production total costs (Centre for Communication and Development, undated:25). Workers
hired for the eight month period of shrimp production leave their jobs after that period
and are hired afresh every year. Average wages in the mid-1980s were about Rs. 180 per
month (at 1985 exchange rates, approximately US$ 18). The wages of managers and guards in
the mid-1980s were around Rs. 300 (or about US$ 30) a month. Workers lived on the site and
often worked at night when the shrimp feed. A West Bengal non-governmental organization
says: "the conditions of work and employment are totally dependent on the owners'
whims and fancies". Generally about half of the people employed in the Jalkar
come from distant villages, especially the guards who are believed to be more reliable if
they have no local connections. In the Jalkar system, shrimp production provides
twice as much money income to the pond- or Jalkar-owner than would rice production.
The benefit to small landowners who are forced to lease their land has been considerably
less. In some cases, their rental income has been inferior to what they could gain from
rice paddy cultivation, especially if direct consumption benefits are taken into account
(Centre for Communication and Development, undated).
These employment and labour figures do not show the employment lost with
the development of shrimp farms. Such social costs and environmental
"externalities" will be discussed later. It appears from the available
literature that for similar areas both traditional aquaculture and agriculture generate
more employment than does commercial shrimp farming. In any event, the type of employment
generated by shrimp farms is often not available to local people (Snedaker et al., 1986;
Centre for Communication and Development, undated). In Bangladesh, the Department of
Fisheries estimates that about 75 per cent of the shrimp farmers in the early 1970s were
not natives of the coastal areas in Khulna and Satkhira districts (Sultana, 1994:2). In
the sample village of Chokoria Sundarban area[12], only
10 out of 300 households obtained leases of shrimp ponds. Leases of 10 acre (4 hectare)
shrimp farms in a former mangrove area were beyond the reach of most local farmers
(Sultana, 1994:7-9). Many of the shrimp farm owners came from the business or service
sector. In the Polder 17/2 area[13], they leased land
from local farmers as well as from the government and inundated several hectares beyond
the leased land, forcing other land users out of the area and into less secure or more
difficult income earning activities (Sultana, 1994: 11).
Extensive shrimp farms produce about one ton of product per growing cycle
per ten or more hectares of land. Intensive farms require important investments in other
capital besides land (in order to increase stocking densities, water exchange capacities,
etc.). Overall production costs (including construction and operating costs) for
traditional extensive methods are estimated at US$ 1-3 per kilogram of live shrimp. Land
and labour are the principal inputs of extensive shrimp farming. These production costs
are commonly undervalued in less developed countries. On the other hand, purchased inputs,
costs of energy and technical devices, on which more intensive methods rely, tend to
reflect their prices in world markets. Operating costs for semi-intensive and intensive
farms range from US$ 3-6 per kilogram of live shrimp (Rosenberry, 1993:23-24).
National and Transnational Investors and Agencies
Shrimp farm owners or operators producing for international markets have
to adopt more intensive technologies in order to remain competitive as there are sharp
limits to the land and water resources still available for extensive production. This
requires access to financial resources and expensive technology. These are provided most
of the time by urban entrepreneurs supported by foreign investors and industries. Wealthy
investors, such as transnational corporations, tend to be very influential and therefore
likely to obtain preferential access to public or private lands, water, credits, markets,
tax holidays, subsidies, licences, foreign exchange and technology (FAO/NACA, 1994a:29;
Ben-Yami, 1986; Kowalewski, 1987).
The allocation of resources for shrimp farming, and the distribution of
benefits, varies greatly from one social context to another. For instance, in the
Philippines where the control of land and other resources has traditionally been highly
concentrated with a small élite, most shrimp production is in the hands of a few large
entrepreneurs and investors. In Thailand, however, land ownership has, on average, been
rather widely dispersed. There, small- and medium-sized shrimp farmers who were previously
cultivators and fishermen could frequently move into shrimp farming and in this way
improve their incomes substantially. In the 1980s, large feed and other input
manufacturers, processors and marketing companies became increasingly important. They have
played a crucial role in intensifying Thailand's shrimp production and thereby increasing
their own profits. These large enterprises are often joint ventures with transnational
investors based in Japan, Taiwan Province of China, Europe or North America who also
provide additional economic and technical backup.
In most cases the large enterprises do not attempt to own the shrimp
production units. In Thailand in 1990 they owned only some 10 per cent of the total number
of shrimp farms and produced less than 20 per cent of the total output. A few large
corporations, however, had oligopolistic control over the feed production sector, with
only nine enterprises sharing 80 per cent of the market at the beginning of the 1990s. By
promoting co-operatives and societies in which the shrimp farm owner or farmer was only
one member, these large enterprises could closely control production practices
(prescribing exactly the type and quantity of inputs to use and having exclusive control
over the output) (Weigel, 1993:399).[14] In this way
they could reap profits while passing on many of the risks to small
"independent" producers. Shrimp farmers' profits tend to fluctuate greatly from
one crop cycle or year to another. Processors and trading enterprises have more stable
incomes, as they tend to have important shares of the market among the 50 countries which
cultivate shrimp. The trend is to encourage intensive shrimp farms developed on the
farmers' own units but with substantial financial and technical backing (Platteau, 1989).
Governments have often played an essential role in launching commercial
shrimp production. The state has frequently provided cheap credits and facilitated access
to land, water and modern inputs as well as to export markets. Traditional common property
management systems are seldom suitable for shrimp production geared to export markets.
Common property régimes previously accommodated seasonal multicrop aquaculture combined
with agriculture for local consumption. The high returns in convertible foreign currency
from shrimp aquaculture make it an industry which has been greatly favoured by
governments, as well as by national and transnational banks: "The state (is)
transforming multiple-use/multiple-user resources historically used by coastal residents
to single-use private property owned by local and national élites ..." (Bailey,
1988:32).
A study concentrating on Amphoe Hua Sai and Ranot, two districts of
southern Thailand[15], reports that around 3,000 shrimp
farmers controlled 20,876 rais (about 3,367 hectares) in ponds. Most of these pond owners
(about 93 per cent) were also their operators, but this area seems to be exceptional in
this respect. The financial incentives to enter the shrimp business were very high. Thai
aquaculturists in the Ranot district, who were previously growing mainly rice, increased
their income by as much as ten times (Aquastar Laboratories Ltd., 1994:7-8). Most of their
ponds were used intensively. In the districts studied, shrimp farmers were moving in from
other areas where they had been producing shrimp for several years (most of them from
three to five years) (NACA, 1994b:21-22). Shrimp farming is a full-time activity for most
shrimp farmers in this area, as 80 per cent of shrimp farmers reported that shrimp were
their only source of income.
For all Thailand, however, it was estimated that 70 per cent of all shrimp
producers had other sources of income: 32 per cent as traders, 16 per cent as fishermen, 8
per cent as rice farmers, 7 per cent as labourers and another 7 per cent as government
employees (NACA, 1994b:22). It was estimated that only 20 per cent of the shrimp farmers
owned their farms, that 77 per cent had access to the land through a collaboration with
relatives and friends[16], and that only 3 per cent of
the shrimp farms were actually owned by a company.[17]
These figures, however, do not show how much pond area each of these groups controls. As
shown above, the influence of large corporations in the shrimp industry does not depend on
their ownership of the land under production. Large corporations control financial and
technical inputs as well as processing and marketing channels. In this way they indirectly
controlled in 1991 about 76 per cent of all Thai shrimp farms (ibid.:121, table 37).
Thai aquaculture has thrived in part due to the phenomenal recent growth
of the Gulf of Thailand trawl fishery. Thai trawlers fished down the food chain to smaller
and smaller fish. In this way their total fish production did not fall substantially, but
70 per cent of their landings were "trash fish" used as animal feed. "The
trawl fishery of the Gulf has therefore become a fish meal producer that has enabled the
aquaculture industry to develop with relatively low feed costs" (Christy et al.,
undated:52).
The case of Aquastar, a large Thai corporation active in the shrimp
industry, shows how multinational capital is used, with the active support of governments
and banks, for vertically integrating the shrimp production chain.[18] Aquastar provides farmers with credit, production
inputs, technical know-how and other devices for their entry into shrimp production. An
arrangement with the Bank of Thailand and the Bank of Asia allows the farmers to have
access to low interest loans for construction and operating costs. The Thai Lands
Department looks at the individual land holding of each farmer and "redraws the land
boundaries in order to give each farmer clear title to the area of his pond". We will
see in the next section that this procedure of "land consolidation" often occurs
at the expense of customary local users having less formalized access rights (Fegan,
1994:18).
The World Bank participated actively in the launching of the shrimp
industry in Asia. Out of an investment of US$ 1.7 billion in 1992 for Indian agriculture
and fisheries, the World Bank allocated US$ 425 million for aquaculture development
(Mukherjee, 1994). A substantial part of this sum seems to be destined for intensification
and expansion of shrimp ponds. The involvement of the World Bank in shrimp aquaculture,
and the development of related hatcheries and other shrimp facilities, illustrates the
trend towards internationally organized vertical integration of this industry (O'Neil,
1994:10-11; Sfeir-Younis and Donaldson, 1984). We do not know how much the World Bank has
actually invested in shrimp aquaculture in tropical countries, but partial and dispersed
information suggest the importance of these credits.[19]
In 1985 the Bank planned to invest US$ 200 million in aquaculture projects dispersed in
Indonesia, Thailand, the Philippines, Sri Lanka, Malaysia, Bangladesh and China (Scura,
1985, cited in Bailey, 1988:33).
Recently, in India, the World Bank group's IDA has been actively promoting
sizeable shrimp farming projects in West Bengal, Orissa and Andra Pradesh. Its loans help
finance development of 13 sites covering a total land area of about 6,000 hectares with a
net water-spread area of about 3,800 hectares. The land is divided into shrimp farms of
0.5 to one hectare. It is presumed that each pond will be leased to one small farmer
family beneficiary, according to the project document. The project is meant to provide
employment and income for 5,200 families. Each shrimp farmer would have the possibility of
earning about Rs. 30,000 (about US$ 900) per year (Fish Farming International,
1994a:4). Water exchange, technical advice and the management of common facilities
(including channels) and services (including technical advice and provision of inputs)
would be the responsibility of the Brackish Water Fish Farming Development Agency financed
through an annual service charge levied on behalf of each farm unit (FAO/NACA,
1994b:85-87). Overall, the World Bank would invest Rs. 400,000 per hectare (about US$
12,000).
The donors' justification for their investments in aquaculture has been
that it is going to help meet developing countries' food needs. In practice, funds
destined for aquaculture have been largely diverted into the production of farmed shrimp
which is a luxury export commodity, even though original plans often called for fin-fish
production for domestic consumption (Luna, 1984)[20].
Incomes reaching the producing areas are unevenly and unsustainably allocated among
different groups of its populations. Support for inland small-scale fin-fish aquaculture,
which is less capital intensive, but is more efficient in producing protein to meet the
local population's requirements, is often diminished to the extent shrimp farming has been
favoured (Bailey and Skladany, 1991:66-73).
Fry Collectors and Hatchery Workers
Shrimp farming has until recently depended primarily on wild shrimp fry
(larvae and post-larvae) which ranged second after feed expenses in the production costs
of semi- and intensive shrimp farms. In many cases, the collection of fry led to the local
depletion of wild shrimp. High technology hatcheries are now being rapidly installed.
Actually, considerable employment was created for local people, mostly women and children,
in the collection of wild fry from estuarine waters. Local employment and complementary
income opportunities will decrease to the extent this activity is displaced by hatcheries,
but this is hardly mentioned in the literature. There were about 50,000 part-time fry
collectors in West Bengal for about 33,000 hectares in shrimp culture (FAO/NACA,
1994b:58). For 100 shrimp post-larvae, the collector got approximately US$ 1, but what
this income means to local people in different areas raises many questions which can only
be answered by case studies. There are a number of other unanswered questions as well. How
much post-larvae can one gather in how much time? To what extent is shrimp fry collection
combined with other tasks? Who is earning and controlling the resulting income?
Between 1993 and 1994, for all Asia, the number of shrimp hatcheries
doubled, according to Rosenberry, from 2,759 to 4,208 (Rosenberry, 1993, 1994b). The
installation of these hatcheries is often promoted with governmental support. In
Bangladesh in 1993, for example, the government owned two of the country's four
hatcheries. In order to facilitate the further development of the shrimp industry, the
government of Bangladesh has recently decided to sell its hatcheries to the private
sector. It also provided US$ 50 million in credit to encourage the installation of new
shrimp farms. The government hoped to double export earnings from shrimp in 1994, and
again in 1995, to reach US$ 625 million (McElroy, 1993-1994).
Current or future loss of traditional fishery productivity implied by the
excessive collection of fry should be weighed, on a case by case basis, against the
current employment and revenue opportunities generated through the collection of wild fry.
As will be discussed later, such an analysis should also include the risks of reduced
biodiversity induced by the over-exploitation of wild fry.[21]
Risks of biodiversity loss due to the collection of wild shrimp fry should also be weighed
against the risks of escape from hatcheries of shrimp that are disease contaminated or
have possibly been rendered dangerous for other species through genetic manipulation
(Pullin, 1992). Hatcheries may not be the only alternative to shrimp fry. Prudent
management of natural nursery habitats, such as mangroves, could possibly make both
traditional fishery production and wild shrimp fry collection for limited shrimp
aquaculture compatible.
Manufacturers, Processors and Marketing Agents
Shrimp production involves manufacture of numerous inputs such as shrimp
feed, fertilizers, pesticides and veterinary drugs, as well as of technical devices for
water treatment and pond operation. The off-farm post-harvest production links also
include processors and marketing agents (packaging, transport, export-importers,
industries further transforming the product, different levels of wholesalers and
retailers, restaurants and supermarkets). There are, however, few data available
concerning the social composition, employment conditions and organizational structure of
processing and marketing links in the shrimp production chain. A study conducted in
Indonesia in 1984 reported that a cold storage factory hired mostly young women who earned
no more than US$ 1 per day (Yoshinori, 1987). As was seen above, with the growth and
intensification of the shrimp industry, manufacturers, processors and marketing agents are
becoming increasingly powerful actors in the production chain. These sectors have grown
even faster than the shrimp farming sector itself; for instance, several Asian countries
report excessive freezing facilities. These providers of inputs and services in turn push
direct producers to expand and intensify their production.
It is difficult to separate those off-farm related industrial and
commercial activities which are exclusively related to shrimp aquaculture from those which
are related to overall aquaculture production. The feeds, pharmaceuticals, pesticides,
technical tools and infrastructure (such as transportation, port and freezing facilities
etc.) are similar and largely interchangeable between shrimp and other aquacultural and
fishery producers. The technology and inputs are mostly manufactured in the higher income
countries of Europe, North America and Asia. Processing involves deheading, skinning,
cleaning, sorting, weighing and freezing the shrimp. In most countries it implies low-paid
and precarious employment done mostly by women, and often also by children (Sultana,
1994:13).
The numbers of intermediaries vary widely, as do their role and economic
power. In Japan, shrimp-specialized primary wholesalers handle 70 per cent of imported
shrimp the remainder being distributed through central wholesale markets.
International standards for shrimp exports and imports have already been established,
which facilitates marketing (ITC/UNCTAD/GATT, 1991). There are cases where each link of
the production chain belongs to a different actor. City based agents or intermediaries may
bring the shrimp to the freezing and packaging plants. The same, or another agent, may
take them for export. Marketing agents may play an important role in exchanging the
information necessary to equate supply and demand, to control quality and to facilitate
transfer of technology. A study conducted in Bangladesh found that traders did not collude
to exploit producers. There was considerable competition among traders that allowed
producers to secure fairly equitable deals (de Campos Guimarăes, 1989). In Japan,
however, distributors tend to band together to plan their purchases at stable price and
quality (Tradescope, 1992). As we said earlier, the general tendency is towards
vertical integration of the production chain, with large seafood companies as providers of
inputs, technology and credits increasingly controlling all stages from production to
packaging and marketing[22].
High Purchasing-Power Consumers
The United States is now the world's largest shrimp market. It has been
estimated that at least 50 per cent of the shrimp imported into the United States comes
from aquaculture (Csavas, 1993:45). The United States imports primarily from Ecuador,
Thailand, China, Bangladesh and India. In 1992, United States shrimp consumption reached
2.5 pounds (1.1 kilograms) per capita (Rosenberry, 1993:32). Japan accounts for a third of
international trade in seafood, and it imports more than 4 million tons of fish products
from over 120 countries each year (Kakuta, 1994). The strong yen helped Japanese importers
to dominate the market until 1992. The Japanese per capita consumption rate of shrimp
reached a record of 3 kilograms per year in 1989. The value of cultured shrimp in Japanese
imports of seafood increased from 29 per cent of the total in 1986 to 46 per cent in 1991.[23] Europe[24] is also
increasing its overall shrimp imports; from 1993 to 1994 alone they rose by 7 per cent
(FAO, 1994:398-399). Besides, there is a growing market among the expanding middle- and
upper-classes of the newly industrializing Asian countries.
According to FAO, worldwide shrimp consumption grew by nearly 4 per cent
annually between 1970-1988 (Maw Cheng Yang, cited by Rosenberry, 1993:34). As shown in
table 1 and the related graph, production of farmed shrimp has been increasing much more
rapidly than shrimp captured at sea. In the early 1990s, overall shrimp production was
increasing faster than demand, when farmed and captured shrimp production combined grew by
an average of 156,000 tons per year from 1990 through 1992.[25]
A sudden global production collapse in 1993 induced overall prices to rise by 30 per cent
between 1993-1994 (Renard, 1995:47). Thai producers argue that annual consumption growth
of between 2 and 3 per cent would be more realistic for the near future and that a
production increase in 1994 below 75,000 metric tons might have helped prevent shrimp
prices from falling. Fluctuations in shrimp prices make it a risky venture for producers,
but attract the interest of speculators.
As a luxury item, shrimp is subject to great fluctuations in demand.
Demand could suddenly collapse if consumers became widely convinced that the consumption
of shrimp was hazardous to health or that shrimp were produced in a socially and
environmentally unsustainable manner.[26] Until
recently, cultured shrimp had the reputation of being fresher and safer to consume than
captured shrimp. Cultured shrimp, however, are also prone to bacteriological, viral or
chemical contamination, leading to health problems that may be publicized and deter
consumers (Barg, 1992; Martínez-Espinosa and Barg, 1993). There are some controls by
importers; Japanese buyers, for example, have a network of supervisors to ensure that
quality requirements are met during production (Rosenberry, 1993:10). The United States
Food and Drug Administration samples imported seafood to prevent entry of products that
have been adulterated or spoiled or contain poisonous and non-allowed additives (Martin
and Flick, 1990:351-364). In addition, the culinary quality of cultivated shrimp seems to
deteriorate with artificial feeding. Japanese consumers have recently been reported to
prefer captured shrimp which, with modern freezing techniques installed on shrimp
trawlers, have superior freshness and quality (Rosenberry, 1993:32).
Large corporations that control the whole production chain claim that they
are more capable of controlling health and environmental factors than are small producers.
They often attempt to use this argument to provide themselves with a competitive advantage
in order to by-pass smaller or less integrated production units (Weigel, 1993). But the
volatility of the market induces commercial producers to maximize short-term profits and
to neglect investments for making the industry environmentally and socially more
sustainable.
Footnotes
10. The development of about 30,000 hectares of
shrimp ponds would employ about 30,000 to 40,000 people on a full-time basis for an
investment of approximately US$ 100 million (FAO/NACA, 1994b:55).
11. One bigha equals 0.67 hectares.
12. In Cox's Bazar District.
13. In the Dumuria Thana of Khulna District.
14. Some of these large enterprises include
Charoen Prokphand, S.T.C. Feedmil Co., Aquastar Co., Unicord Feed Co., Lee Feed Mill Co.,
Krungthai Feed Mill Co.; large transnational corporations such as Mitsubshi and Cargill
are also involved.
15. Provinces of Nakhorn Si Thammarat and
Sonkhala.
16. The study does not say who those relatives
and friends are and what type of contract binds their support.
17. This illustrates the extremely approximate
nature of the data because Weigel, cited in an earlier paragraph, estimated 10 per cent.
18. This enterprise is currently also investing
in India and other South-East Asian countries.
19. The World Bank has not released recent
information on its credit policy concerning shrimp aquaculture, but an undated technical
paper (from the late 1980s) mentions a sum of US$ 180 million investment over five years
(Christy, et al., undated).
20. While multicropping of shrimp with milkfish
appreciated as a source of protein in many developing countries is
technically feasible, economic conditions do not encourage it. In 1984, in South Sulawesi
(Indonesia), a kilogram of prawn was worth four or five times a kilogram of milkfish
(Yosuke, 1987:17).
21. "For every single shrimp prawn in the
pond almost a hundred other fish or shrimp are killed" (Csavas, 1988 or 1989:84).
22. In Thailand, the Aquastar corporation is an
example. An example in Indonesia is the Indonusa Royal Group, which processes and packages
shrimp and other seafood products as well as owning over 100 hectares of shrimp ponds.
23. In 1993, Japanese shrimp imports (frozen,
fresh and chilled) reached 301,271 metric tons which is three times the amount of 1984
(FAO, 1994).
24. FAO gives estimates for European imports of
cultivated and captured (frozen, fresh and chilled) shrimp for the following countries:
Spain, France, Denmark, Italy, United Kingdom, Belgium, Germany, Sweden, the Netherlands,
Portugal, Norway, Switzerland, Ireland, Austria and Poland (FAO, 1994).
25. As was seen in the second section of this
report, cultured shrimp production fell in 1993, but again grew substantially in 1994.
26. An Ecuadorian environmental group
Accion Ecologica has already launched a boycott to protest against shrimp
aquaculture that has meant the destruction of vast stretches of the country's mangroves
(Kohr, 1995). |