|
4. The Dynamics of
the Commons Common property tenure and usufruct
systems are central to many traditional management systems. Rural Third World communities
often do not have as pervasive a sense of individual private property ownership as has
developed in the industrialized world instead, systems of group ownership prevail.
It has, until fairly recently, been part of the conventional wisdom to believe that common
property systems were inherently less productive, and more susceptible to degradation,
than private property régimes. This belief was due to the metaphor of the "tragedy
of the commons" (generally attributed to Hardin, 1968), which maintained that,
because no individual would have to pay the full costs of overexploitation, it would be in
each individual's interest to extract as much as possible from the resource base, with the
result that commonly held resources would inevitably be degraded. This view has largely
lost theoretical support in recent years as the distinction between common property
régimes (which consist in essence of jointly held property) and open access systems
(which have no restrictions on resource use, and which are in fact subject to degradation)
has become clear, and as more empirical studies have come out demonstrating the economic
value of the commons (Bromley and Cernea, 1989).
Jodha's (1990) study has been particularly valuable in
this latter regard. Research undertaken in 82 villages in India revealed that the poor
obtain approximately one-fifth of their household income directly from common property
resources, which in addition provide them with more than one-third of their farm inputs.
Without the availability of common grazing lands in these communities, over half of the
lands currently under food and cash crops would have to be diverted to fodder crops, or
else livestock would have to be significantly cut, with a consequent drop in draft power
and manure. In addition, Jodha argued, state interventions which have been undertaken to
privatize common property, even when such interventions have been developed with the
specific aim of helping the poor, have resulted in overall declines in the conditions of
poor households.
However, in spite of the fact that the "tragedy of
the commons" scenario is no longer accepted by many development theorists, the
metaphor remains a powerful influence on or at least a strong basis for the
rationalization of the policies of both national governments and international
development agencies which advocate settling pastoralists (Lane, 1990; Adams, 1990),
privatizing fishing grounds (Baines, 1989; Polunin, 1985), and supplanting traditional
agricultural systems (Moorehead, 1989; Diegues, 1990). As Baines argues, "there is a
consistent tendency by agents of resource development to characterize traditional forms of
resource administration as 'problems' impeding development" (Baines, 1989: 278). Thus
as late as 1989, an official of the Tanzanian Ministry of Agriculture wrote, in terms
directly recalling Hardin:
...[the] practice of grazing private livestock
on communal land constitutes the single major constraint to improved management of the
natural pasture lands. The inevitable result of this system of livestock production is
that the cattle owners keep excessive numbers of livestock which in turn leads to
overgrazing, soil degradation, low fertility and high mortality rates. However, in order
to allow for the best possible care of the agricultural land in the future, users will be
allocated land on the basis of lease-hold, thus ensuring that they get full legal
protection.... restriction of animal numbers to any reasonable balance with the forage
resource has proved difficult due to lack of land ownership rights and communal land
ownership (quoted in Lane, 1990: 16).
In fact, however, as Adams (1990) argues, the symptoms of
environmental degradation in arid lands including the concentration of pastoralists
are often mistaken for the cause. That is, when pastoralists are restricted to the
utilization of only part of the lands they have traditionally grazed, they are prevented
from managing the remaining land in a sustainable manner.
A key factor underlying the continued persuasive power of
the tragedy of the commons metaphor is the belief that private land ownership gives
individuals increased incentives for managing their resources sustainably. The argument is
made that only people who have secure tenure over their landholdings will have the
motivation to invest in the long-term undertakings necessary to ensure the continued
yields of fragile environments. Indeed, several studies have shown the deleterious effects
that lack of secure land tenure has had on local participation rates in environmental
rehabilitation projects (Stĺhl, 1990). In most of these cases, however, lack of secure
tenure is due not to the absence of private ownership as such, but rather to the fact that
existing social structures allow those who control usufruct rights whether they be
individuals, groups, corporations or governments to grant or withdraw these rights
at will.
Common property management systems thus mistakenly get
tarred with the same brush as some nationalized agricultural schemes, which, though in
theory have the potential to be quite productive, in practice often suffer from unwieldy
bureaucracies, insufficient resources, and the necessity of conforming to the demands of
the international financial community. The actual or potential policy changes caused by
these constraints create insecurity among the affected peasant farmers or pastoralists.
Moreover, as Bromley and Cernea (1989) point out, the appearance that private property is
more stable and adaptive than common property is due to the fact that the rights of
exclusion for private property owners are generally upheld by the state: that is, the
customary ability of private owners to exclude others from utilizing their land has been
formalized and codified in law. On the other hand, the equally essential common property
rights of exclusion, which have a firm basis and long history in common law, have been
substantially eroded through the active or benign neglect of the state, and common
property tenants are thus deprived of the legal protection afforded private owners.
In addition, it is clear that private ownership, secure
land tenure, and sustainable resource use are not inevitably or intrinsically linked. For
instance, small land owners who are obliged to go deeply in debt each season risk losing
their land after a bad harvest; large land owners often show no qualms about clearing
rainforests for short-term gains, even when it is clear that the resulting pasture lands
will become barren in only a few years. Bandyopadhyay (1990) demonstrated that in certain
communities in India, common property resources are better safeguarded than private
property resources. The short time preferences of the private owners and their ability to
abandon degraded lands once maximum resources had been extracted, mean that they do not
have the same incentives for environmental preservation that exist in communities whose
families have inhabited a region for generations, and whose descendants will continue to
inhabit it for generations to come. Kurien found the same phenomenon in a study of common
fishing grounds:
" For the fishermen, their future lies in the sea and its common resources. For
capitalists, given their short-term perspective and under the given conditions of
investment, the ratio of profits from indiscriminate harvesting of the commons to the
profits from regulated and sustainable harvesting are large. For them it actually pays to
bring ruin to the commons"! (Kurien, 1991: 35)
|