The World Bank Group. Global Development Finance 1998 Foreign direct investment has surged in the 1990s
Foreign direct investment (FDI) in developing countries was $120
billion in 1997, slightly above the $119 billion of 1996 and five times the level of 1990.
The ratio of FDI to GDP in developing countries jumped from 0.8 percent in 1991 to 2.0
percent in 1997. Developing countries have also increased their share of global FDI flows,
from 21 percent in 1991 to an estimated 36 percent in 1997 (figure 1.6).
Why the growth of FDI inflows?
The surge in net FDI flows during the 1990s has been spurred
mainly by three factors: developing countries liberalization of their economies,
particularly privatization and the lifting of restrictions on FDI; strong growth in the
GDP and trade of the major developing country recipients of FDI flows; and the falling
cost and rising quality of communication and transportation services, which encouraged
private corporations to shift toward more integrated global investment and production.
Like trade, FDI provides an important channel for global integration and technology
transfer.
Multinational corporations took advantage of the liberalization
of the rules governing FDI in developing countries and the privatization of state-owned
enterprises to access new markets and resources. The largest FDI source countries
increased their FDI in developing countries, both in absolute amounts and as a share of
total stocks. Notably, the share of developing countries in the stock of the outward FDI
of the five main FDI sourcesthe United States, Japan, Germany, the United Kingdom,
and Franceincreased during the 1990s in all but Japan. And in Japan the share
declined only marginally in the 1990s, mainly because of its large new investments in
North America. Still, more than 30 percent of Japans outward FDI stock remains in
developing countries.
FDI concentration and low-income countries
Not all developing countries shared in the rapid growth of FDI
during the 1990s. Almost three-quarters of net FDI flows to developing countries has gone
to just 10 countries (table 1.8). The concentration rate remains high, but it has eased
somewhat in recent years, reflecting growing access to FDI.
Table 1.8 FDI flows
to the top ten recipient developing countries, 1991, 1994, and 1997
(billions of U.S. dollars)
Country |
1991 |
Country |
1994 |
Country |
1997a |
Mexico |
4.7 |
China |
33.8 |
China |
37.0 |
China |
4.3 |
Mexico |
11.0 |
Brazil |
15.8 |
Malaysia |
4.0 |
Malaysia |
4.3 |
Mexico |
8.1 |
Argentina |
2.4 |
Peru |
3.1 |
Indonesia |
5.8 |
Thailand |
2.0 |
Brazil |
3.1 |
Poland |
4.5 |
Venezuela |
1.9 |
Argentina |
3.1 |
Malaysia |
4.1 |
Indonesia |
1.5 |
Indonesia |
2.1 |
Argentina |
3.8 |
Hungary |
1.5 |
Nigeria |
1.9 |
Chile |
3.5 |
Brazil |
1.1 |
Poland |
1.9 |
India |
3.1 |
Turkey |
0.8 |
Chile |
1.8 |
Venezuela |
2.9 |
Top ten share in FDI to all
developing countries (percent) |
74.2 |
|
76.1 |
|
72.3 |
a. Preliminary.
Source: World Bank data and staff estimates.
Back to top
Back to Contents
Most of the top recipients of FDI are middle-income countries,
reflecting their large markets and rapid growth in recent years. The only low-income
countries in the top 10 in 1997 were China and India. The ratio of FDI flows to GDP has
remained smaller in low-income countries (excluding China) than in middle-income countries
throughout the 1990s (table 1.9). Recently, however, some low-income countries besides
China and India have begun to receive large amounts of FDI. FDI flows to Vietnam have
increased significantly, from about $380 million a year in 199193 to $1.3 billion a
year in 199597. Some countries, such as Nigeria, have long been large recipients of
FDI in natural resource sectors. But many small, poor countries (especially in Africa)
receive little foreign investment, often because of an unfavorable business environment
(poor policies, unstable government, civil strife, weak infrastructure, poorly trained
workforce) or a small domestic market.
Table 1.9 FDI flows to
developing countries by income group, 1990-97
(percentage of GDP)
Income group |
1990 |
1991 |
1992 |
1993 |
1994 |
1995 |
1996 |
1997 a/ |
All developing countries |
0.6 |
0.8 |
1.1 |
1.6 |
2.0 |
2.1 |
2.0 |
2.0 |
Low-income |
0.5 |
0.8 |
1.5 |
3.4 |
3.7 |
3.5 |
3.0 |
2.8 |
Excluding China |
0.2 |
0.6 |
0.6 |
0.9 |
1.0 |
1.3 |
1.2 |
1.2 |
China |
1.0 |
1.2 |
2.7 |
6.4 |
6.5 |
5.4 |
4.7 |
4.2 |
Middle-income |
0.6 |
0.8 |
0.9 |
1.0 |
1.4 |
1.6 |
1.6 |
1.8 |
Lower-middle-income |
0.4 |
0.5 |
0.6 |
0.7 |
1.2 |
1.4 |
1.4 |
1.3 |
Upper-middle-income |
0.8 |
1.1 |
1.3 |
1.3 |
1.6 |
1.8 |
1.9 |
2.2 |
a. Preliminary.
Source: World Bank data.
Moderating growth in 1997
After growing strongly for several years, FDI leveled off in
1997. Preliminary estimates indicate that net FDI flows to developing countries remained
high in 1997, at $120 billion, but only slightly above the $119 billion in 1996. Still,
net FDI flows continued to be the largest component of external resource flows to
developing countries. The largest reversal in the upward trend occurred in East Asia and
the Pacific, where flows declined 9 percent in 1997, to $53 billion (figure 1.7). FDI
flows to Indonesia fell 27 percent, and flows to China fell an estimated 10 percent (in
part simply a reflection of the surge in FDI in 1996 as investors sought to take advantage
of preferential tax treatment that expired that year). By contrast, flows to Latin America
and the Caribbean rose 10 percent, to $42 billion. Large privatization projects in
infrastructure and other services (notably in Brazil), better economic performance
(Mexico), ongoing liberalization measures (particularly in financial services), and strong
flows into Mercosur and among its members all contributed to Latin Americas FDI
performance in 1997.
During the 1990s active privatization programs in many developing
countries generated a steady stream of FDI inflows, attracting some $60 billion$15
billion in 1997 alone (figure 1.8). Brazil, Venezuela, and some other countries
experienced large increases in FDI through privatization transactions in 1997, while
Hungary, Peru, and others saw large declines in FDI in 1997 as privatization programs
slowed or ended.
Back to top
Back to Contents
Growth of FDI in service sectors
FDI also flowed heavily into services during the 1990s. Several
countries attracted especially large shares of FDI to their service sectors (table 1.10).
Japan and the United States (which account for nearly half of the stock of FDI in
developing countries) both showed large shares of services in their FDI to developing
countries. Services account for 58 percent of the total stock of FDI in developing
countries that originates from Japanese firms, while the share of services in the stock of
U.S. FDI in developing countries has nearly doubled in the past decade (figure 1.9). A
similar trend is observed in most major FDI source countries, except for the United
Kingdom.
Table 1.10 FDI in
selected developing countries, by sector
(percentage of total stock)
Country |
Year |
Primary |
Secondary |
Tertiary |
Argentina |
1990 |
16.3 |
35.3 |
48.4 |
|
1994 |
12.7 |
34.8 |
52.5 |
Brazil |
1990 |
16.1 |
70.4 |
13.6 |
|
1995 |
12.6 |
68.1 |
19.4 |
Czech Republic |
1992 |
1.4 |
84.4 |
14.2 |
|
1996 |
5.4 |
50.8 |
43.7 |
Hungary |
1992 |
2.3 |
52.9 |
44.8 |
|
1996 |
2.5 |
40.3 |
57.2 |
Indonesia |
1990 |
16.1 |
70.4 |
13.6 |
|
1995 |
12.6 |
68.1 |
19.4 |
Peru |
1990 |
37.9 |
34.4 |
27.7 |
|
1996 |
19.6 |
17.2 |
63.2 |
Thailand |
1990 |
6.1 |
37.8 |
56.1 |
|
1996 |
3.9 |
33.4 |
62.7 |
Source: World Bank staff calculations based on national
sources.
Back to top
Back to Contents
Several factors have contributed to the growing importance of
services in FDI flows. Developing countries are lucrative markets for multinational
service providers, and many services firms need a physical presence in the market to
compete effectively (UNCTAD 1996). Services have also become more attractive now that
advances in communications technology allow separated-service providers (data processing,
software development) to reap the cost advantages of developing countries (Allen and
Morton 1994). Liberalization of FDI regimes and privatizations of service enterprises have
also accelerated the rush of FDI to services. Overall, some 40 percent of the revenues
generated by developing countries through privatization programs during the 1990s have
been directed to services, and this share has increased rapidly in the past few years. In
Brazil, the largest FDI recipient through privatization operations in 1997, roughly 70
percent of the revenues were raised in service sectors such as telecommunications, power,
transport, and finance.
The rapid growth of FDI in services reflects a fundamental change
in the role of the private sector in providing services. Technological changes and
regulatory innovations have made it possible to open these services to market forces, thus
encouraging competition, which can bring substantial benefits for consumers. Greater
private investment in services can also free scarce public resources for pressing social
needs. To realize these opportunities, governments will need to ensure that price and
regulatory rules enable service providers to operate on a sound commercial basis.
FDI outflows during the 1990s
Between 1991 and 1996 (the latest year for which reliable numbers
are available) the dollar value of FDI outflows from developing countries increased by
more than three and a half times to $11.1 billion, indicating the growing integration of
developing economies in world markets (table 1.11). China is not only the largest
recipient among developing countries, but also the largest investor, followed by Malaysia,
Chile, Brazil, Thailand, and South Africa.
Back to top
Back to Contents
Table 1.11 FDI
outflows from developing countries,199196
(billions of U.S. dollars)
Country |
1991 |
1992 |
1993 |
1994 |
1995 |
1996 |
All developing countries |
3.0 |
7.3 |
9.4 |
10.1 |
11.3 |
11.1 |
China |
0.9 |
4.0 |
4.4 |
2.0 |
2.0 |
2.2 |
Malaysia |
0.4 |
0.5 |
1.3 |
1.8 |
2.6 |
1.9 |
Chile |
0.1 |
0.4 |
0.4 |
0.9 |
0.7 |
1.1 |
Brazil |
1.0 |
0.1 |
0.5 |
1.0 |
1.4 |
1.0 |
Thailand |
0.2 |
0.1 |
0.2 |
0.5 |
0.9 |
0.9 |
South Africa |
0.2 |
0.8 |
0.3 |
0.3 |
0.6 |
0.7 |
Mexico |
0.2 |
0.7 |
0.0 |
1 |
0.6 |
0.6 |
Source: IMF balance of payments data.
Multinationals from these economies are investing predominantly
in other countries in the same region. In Latin America and the Caribbean the
intraregional increase in FDI is driven by increasing liberalization, new investment
opportunities, proximity, and trade integration. In Argentina the stock of FDI originating
from other Latin American countries accounted for 15 percent of its FDI stock in 1994, up
from 11 percent in 1992.
Prospects for FDI flows
What impact the financial crisis in East Asia will have on FDI
flows to developing countries in 1998 is uncertain (see chapter 2). Nevertheless,
medium-term prospects remain good. FDI flows are likely to be supported by strong growth
in developing countries output and exports, greater economic integration and
globalization of production, and continued liberalization of investment rules.
Studies have consistently found a strong, positive correlation
between rapid GDP growth and FDI inflows (figure 1.10), although the direction of
causality is difficult to determine and may go in both directions (Lizondo 1990; Hein
1992). Developing countries average GDP growth rate is projected to exceed 5 percent
over the next 10 years, or about twice the rate in industrial countries, indicating that
developing countries are likely to continue to attract a substantial share of global FDI
(World Bank 1997b).
Back to top
Back to Contents
Trade expansion and export orientation promote FDI flows. The
complementary relationship between FDI and trade flows is well established (Markusen 1983;
Helpman 1984; Pearce 1993; Pfaffermayr 1996). Analysis at both the firm and the country
level shows a strong positive link between foreign investment and trade flows (Eaton and
Tamura 1994; Kawai and Urata 1995). World trade is projected to grow by some 7 percent
annually in the coming years, a further indication of the bright prospects for FDI flows
(World Bank 1997b).
Regional economic integration may induce higher foreign
investment flows. Regional integration agreements can promote FDI flows by expanding
markets. FDI flows tend to rise in the run-up to a regional agreement, as shown by the
increase in FDI flows to Spain and Portugal in the years immediately preceding their entry
into the European Union, EU experiences prior to the 1992 single market, and the rise in
FDI to Mexico before NAFTA. Automobile multinationals are gearing their production to the
entire Mercosur market, even though barriers to automobile trade have not yet been
removed. There is one caveat, however. If regional integration results in increased
distortions (high external trade barriers, market-sharing agreements between ologopolistic
producers), the resulting inefficiencies could outweigh the potential benefits of FDI.
Continuing liberalization of investment rules will further
encourage FDI. More than 50 countries enacted more open laws on foreign investment during
the 1990s, and the number of bilateral investment treaties on the promotion and protection
of foreign investment increased threefold to 1,100 (UNCTAD 1997). There have also been
advances in multilateral instruments with provisions on cross-border investment. The
Multilateral Agreement on Investment, under negotiation among OECD countries since May
1995, would encompass the three cornerstones of FDI rule-making: investment protection,
investment liberalization, and dispute settlement (box 1.3). Recent agreement in the
negotiations over trade in financial services should also encourage increased FDI inflows
in the future.
Box 1.3 Multilateral Agreement on Investment and
developing countries The Multilateral Agreement on Investment is an initiative
of OECD member countries to develop a comprehensive framework for protecting foreign
investors, liberalizing investment, and settling disputes. It seeks to establish a level
playing field for international investors, with uniform rules on market access and legal
security. The agreement is conceived as a free-standing international treaty open to all
OECD members and open to accession by other countries willing to meet its obligations.
Negotiations were launched at the May 1995 OECD ministerial meeting and are expected to be
completed by April 1998 (nearly a year after the originally targeted deadline). Investment
protection provisions are expected to be similar to the best bilateral investment
treaties, including fair and equitable treatment, free transfer abroad of profits and
dividends, and compensation for expropriation. National treatment (treating foreigners no
worse than domestic investors) will be ensured for new investments and for the operation
and expansion of established investments. Dispute settlement procedures will include both
state-to-state recourse (as in the World Trade Organization) and an investor-to-state
mechanism (as in most bilateral investment treaties). Concerns have been raised that the
agreement could be detrimental to developing countries and that with negotiations taking
place within the OECD, the views of developing countries are not represented. However,
five non-OECD members have participated in the talks with observer status (Argentina,
Brazil, Chile, the Slovak Republic, and Hong Kong, China). To accommodate situations where
specific host country circumstancesparticularly in the poorest and least open
countriesmake immediate adoption of certain provisions of a unilateral
liberalization rule such as this agreement too onerous, the OECD allows nonmember
countries to negotiate the conditions of their accession. |
Continue
with Development in private capital flows
Back to top
Back to Contents |