PRESS RELEASE - World Trade Organization
8 October 1999
TRADE LIBERALIZATION
REINFORCES THE NEED FOR
ENVIRONMENTAL COOPERATION
A new WTO Secretariat report argues that international
economic integration and growth reinforce the need for sound environmental policies at the
national and international level. International cooperation is particularly important in
addressing transboundary and global environmental challenges beyond the control of any
individual nation. This would be true even if nations did not trade with one another.
The WTO Secretariat's Trade and Environment Report, to
be released on 14 October 1999, addresses the economic and political economy dimensions of
the interface between trade and environment. The report argues that there is no basis for
the sweeping generalizations that are often heard in the public debate, arguing that trade
is either good for the environment, or bad for the environment. The real world linkages
are a little bit of both, or a shade of grey. "Win-win" outcomes can be assured
through well designed policies in both the trade and environmental fields.
"Every WTO Member Governments supports open trade
because it leads to higher living standards for working families which in turn leads to a
cleaner environment. This report underscores that trade and environment need not be
contradictory but can indeed be complementary," said WTO Director-General, Mike
Moore.
Among the questions the report seeks to answer are the
following: is economic integration a threat to the environment? Does trade undermine the
regulatory efforts of governments to control pollution and resource degradation? How can
we ensure that economic growth driven by trade will help us to move towards a sustainable
use of the world's environmental resources?
Some of the main findings of the report include the
following:
- Most environmental problems result from polluting
production processes, certain kinds of consumption, and the disposal of waste products
trade as such is rarely the root cause of environmental degradation, except for the
pollution associated with transportation of goods;
- Environmental degradation occurs because producers
and consumers are not always required to pay for the costs of their actions;
- Environmental degradation is sometimes accentuated by
policy failures, including subsidies to polluting and resource-degrading activities
such as subsidies to agriculture, fishing and energy;
- Trade would unambiguously raise welfare if proper
environmental policies were in place;
- Trade barriers generally make for poor environmental
policy;
- Not all environmental standards should necessarily be
harmonized across countries;
- The competiveness effects of environmental
regulations are minor for most industries;
- A good environmental profile is often more of an
asset for a firm than a liability in the international market-place, notwithstanding
somewhat higher production costs;
- Little evidence bears out the claim that polluting
industries tend to migrate from developed to developing countries to reduce environmental
compliance costs;
- Yet, environmental measures are sometime defeated
because of concerns about competitiveness, suggesting a need for improved international
cooperation on environmental issues;
- Economic growth, driven by trade, may be part of the
solution to environmental degradation, but it is not sufficient by itself to improve
environmental quality higher incomes must be translated into higher environmental
standards;
- And not all kinds of economic growth are equally
benign for the environment;
- Public accountability and good governance are
essential to good environmental policy, including at the international level;
- Effective international cooperation is essential to
protect the environment, especially in respect of transboundary and global environmental
challenges.
- The cooperative model of the WTO, based on legal
rights and obligations, could potentially serve as a model for a new global architecture
of environmental cooperation.
- Meanwhile, even within its current mandate, the WTO
could do a few important things for the environment. The most obvious contribution would
be to address remaining trade barriers on environmental goods and services in order to
reduce the costs of investing in clean production technologies and environmental
management systems. Another contribution would be to seek reductions in government
subsidies that harm the environment, including energy, agriculture and fishing subsidies.
A number of these points are elaborated briefly in the
attached annex.
Annex
Environmental degradation is driven by market and
policy failures. While trade itself may be associated with environmental problems, such as
pollution arising through the transportation of goods, most problems occur during
production, consumption, and/or the disposal of waste products. Appropriate regulations
and taxes can ensure that environmental impacts are accounted for by producers and
consumers the "Polluter Pays Principle". However, governments may not
only omit to correct market failures, they may also aggravate the problems through
subsidies.
Trade would unambiguously raise welfare if proper
environmental policies were in place. Without adequate environmental policies, trade can
prejudice environmental quality. For example, demand from the world market may encourage
unsustainable logging when no proper management scheme is in place. In other instances,
trade liberalization may mitigate the underlying distortions. For example, a reduction in
fishing subsidies, amounting to some $54 billion annually, would reduce overcapitalisation
in the industry and lessen overfishing.
· Trade barriers are poor environmental policies.
Environmental problems are best addressed at source, whether they involve polluting
production processes or undefined property rights over natural resources. Targeting
indirect linkages, such as exports or imports of goods, can only partially correct market
and policy failures, and at a higher price to society. At the same time, governments have
found trade measures a useful mechanism for encouraging participation in and enforcement
of multilateral environmental agreements in some instances, and for attempting to modify
the behaviour of foreign governments in others. However, the use of trade measures in this
way is fraught with risks for the multilateral trading system, unless accompanied with
rules agreed by all parties.
· Environmental standards should not necessarily be
harmonized. This conclusion refers only to local pollution problems that are
arguably best addressed by standards targeted to the specificities of the local
conditions. Neither poor nor rich communities (countries) are well served by setting
standards at the average. The case is different for transboundary and global problems
where policy harmonization and collective management of common resources is perhaps the
only effective policy option.
The environmental repercussions of trade are
theoretically ambiguous, and depend on three interacting factors: (i) trade-induced
changes in industrial composition, and hence the pollution intensity of national output,
(ii) changes in the overall scale of economic activity, and (iii) changes in production
technology. The net outcome is a priori undetermined. Sweeping generalisations about the
linkages between trade and environment, whether positive or negative generalisations, must
therefore be rejected.
The gains from trade are sufficient to pay for
additional abatement costs. The income gain associated with trade could in principle
pay for the necessary abatement costs and still leave an economic surplus. This has been
shown in various economic simulations. In other words, by combining trade and
environmental reforms one can find ways to raise income and consumption without
compromising the natural environment. At least in this sense, there is no inherent
conflict between trade and environment. Rather, the conflict arises as a result of the
failure of political institutions to address environmental problems, especially those of a
global nature which require a concerted effort to solve.
The competitiveness effects of environmental
regulations are minor. The direct cost of pollution control in the OECD is minor, just a
few percentage points of production costs for most industries. No corresponding estimates
are available for developing countries, but unless the regulatory cost is zero, the cost
savings of moving offshore are less than suggested above. Moreover, some observers have
noted that these numbers are in any event exaggerated. The "Porter hypothesis"
holds that regulatory pressure, just like competitive pressure, encourages industrial
innovations that make production both leaner (less energy and resource demanding) and
cleaner at the same time, thereby offsetting the direct compliance costs. The empirical
evidence partly supports this hypothesis, although it would be wrong to conclude that
environmental regulations do not cost anything. They do cost, but they also bring
significant benefit to society and the quality of life.
Environmental leaders are not less profitable.
Studies that have compared the profitability of firms in the same industry have not found
much evidence that environmental leaders pay a price in terms of reduced profitability.
For several reasons, environmental leaders can often recoup costs in the marketplace.
Firstly, a growing number of consumers are willing to pay a premium for "green
labels." Secondly, firms that accord with the environmental management standards
promulgated by the International Organization for Standardization (ISO 14000) seem to
enjoy certain competitive advantages, including lower liability insurance, less regulatory
oversight, and increased access to customers (including the public sector) that care about
their own environmental reputation.
Polluting industries are not migrating from
developed to developing countries to reduce environmental compliance costs, although there
are of course exceptions. While it is certainly true that developing countries are net
recipients of foreign direct investment, the composition of investments they receive is not
biased towards polluting industries, but rather to labour-intensive industries that
are less polluting on average. What the data tell us is that, to the extent developed
countries are exporting their dirty industries, they are exporting them to each other, not
to less developed economies. This suggests that environmental regulations are at most of
secondary importance for international investment decisions.
Multinational firms are moving towards a policy
of standardised technologies for all their production plants in the world. The reason is
simple. It is less costly to duplicate the home technology than to modify the process in
each country. What is more, the choice of technology is not just based on current
standards, but on what is expected in the future. It makes commercial sense to install
state-of-the-art technology at the time an investment is made rather than retrofitting
abatement equipment at a later stage at a much greater expense. Finally, multinationals
are becoming more sensitive to the reputation they earn in the market place, at least
those multinational firms that are based in countries with an active environmental
community. Market forces often reward good environmental performance rather than cost
savings at any price, including financial markets that react negatively to environmental
mishaps. It has not always been this way, but the tide has changed in recent years. Much
of this advance is thanks to the relentless efforts of non-governmental organizations
around the world that have made consumers sensitive to the environmental profile of
products and producers. In short, when consumers care, producers care.
Yet, environmental measures are sometimes
defeated because of competitiveness concerns. Market forces cannot be entrusted to solve
all problems themselves. Governments must do their part by regulating polluting and
resource degrading activities appropriately. This creates a difficult political dilemma.
If policy makers and voters think that domestic industry is crumbling under
environmental regulations at the expense of domestic investments and jobs, it may be
difficult to forge the necessary political support for new regulatory initiatives. And
this problem may become worse still when trade and investment barriers are removed, since
industries then become more mobile and more difficult to regulate. Indeed, some evidence
suggests that industries often appeal to competitiveness concerns when lobbying against
environmental regulations, and on occasion with some success.
How serious is this problem? It would clearly be
a serious problem if competitiveness concerns prevented environmental standards from being
raised to appropriate levels, or if governments were compelled to build in protectionist
elements in environmental regulations to "compensate" industry for alleged
adverse competitive effects. However, competitiveness concerns could potentially be a
positive force if governments that find it difficult to act individually for political
reasons seek cooperative solutions to environmental problems. The growing number of
multilateral environmental agreements (currently some 216) may be one indication of the
trend in that direction. The lasting effect of "regulatory chill" may then be
more procedural than substantial. That is, initiative may have to shift from the national
to the supranational level, just as we saw a shift from the local to the central level in
federal states in the 1970s to overcome environmental policy foot-dragging at the local
level. Admittedly, however, international cooperation in these matters is not easy to
achieve unless governments are convinced of its urgency.
Is economic growth, driven by trade, part of the
problem or part of the solution? One reason why environmental protection is lagging
in many countries is low incomes. Countries that live on the margin may simply not be able
to afford to set aside resources for pollution abatement, nor may they think that they
should sacrifice their growth prospects to help solve global pollution problems that in
large part have been caused by the consuming life style of richer countries. If poverty is
at the core of the problem, economic growth will be part of the solution, to the extent
that it allows countries to shift gear from more immediate concerns to long run
sustainability issues. Indeed, at least some empirical evidence suggests that
pollution increases at the early stages of development but decreases after a certain
income level has been reached, an observation that has become known in academic circles as
the Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC).
How does trade enter the growth and environment
debate? Trade enters into this debate for several reasons. The most direct reason is that
trade is one cylinder that propels the engine of growth. Another reason is that trade may
affect the shape and relevance of the EKC. It is at least conceivable that the turning
point enjoyed by developed countries as far as certain pollutants are concerned is partly
due to migration of polluting industries to developing countries, although the evidence
does not seem to support this position. A third reason why trade comes into the picture is
the political economy of environmental policy making. Competitive pressure may prevent
environmental standards from being upgraded to turn around the pollution path. Growth
driven by liberalization of the world economy may then defeat the mechanisms that in
principle could generate an environmental Kuznets curve. As observed before, there is some
evidence of a "regulatory chill" which may call for increased policy
coordination among governments.
Economic growth may be part of the solution, but
primarily for local pollution problems. The empirical evidence in support of the EKC
hypothesis is mixed. The evidence suggests that the EKC hypothesis may be valid for some
types of environmental indicators, but equally untrue for other important indicators.
Those indicators that appear to demonstrate some characteristics of an inverted U-shape
pollution path are certain types of local, primarily urban air pollution, and to a lesser
extent some types of freshwater pollutants. In contrast, pollutants of a more global
nature do not seem to accord with the EKC hypothesis, notably emissions of carbon dioxide.
In essence, countries seem more prone to act on pollutants that affect their own backyard
than pollutants that degrade the global environment, although there are also some
encouraging developments in respect of the latter, such as the reductions in
ozone-depleting substances rendered possible by international cooperation under the
Montreal Protocol.
Economic growth is not sufficient for turning
environmental degradation around. It should also be emphasised that nothing in the EKC
literature suggests that environmental degradation will turn around with increasing income
by compelling necessity. If economic incentives facing producers and consumers do not
change with higher incomes, pollution will continue to grow unabated with the growing
scale of economic activity. In other words, income growth, while perhaps a necessary
condition for allowing countries to shift gear from more immediate economic and social
concerns to more long term sustainability issues, is not sufficient to reverse
environmental degradation. Environmental polices must be brought to bear.
Accountability and good governance is critical.
The importance of a democratic political process cannot be underestimated in this regard.
Governments that are not held accountable for their actions, or rather inaction in this
case, may fail to deliver the necessary upgrading of environmental polices. Comparing
countries at the same income level, pollution tends to be worse in countries with skewed
income distribution, a high degree of illiteracy, and few political and civil liberties.
Moreover, these "political access" variables considerably weaken the
relationship between per capita income and environmental quality. This suggests that the
EKC relationship is not so much dependent on income levels per se, but rather on
institutional and democratic reforms that tend to go hand in hand with increased income,
and which are necessary for allowing ordinary citizens to articulate their preferences for
environmental quality and influence the political decision-making process.
Good governance is also needed at the
international level. One of the disturbing conclusions of the empirical literature is that
the turning points of global environmental problems, such as global warming driven by CO2
emissions and other greenhouse gases, are estimated at considerably higher incomes than
more localized problems. One interpretation of this is that people do not care much about
global warming and climate change. They would rather accept the consequences (on behalf of
their children and their children's children) than the costs of curbing emissions. Another
possible reason for political foot-dragging is that governments seek to free ride in the
context of weak political institutions at the international level, including weak
enforcement mechanisms. Indeed, one reason why the WTO has become the focal point for
environmental disputes is that the WTO has an integrated adjudication mechanism backed by
trade sanctions as the ultimate enforcement tool.
Environmental degradation will turn around when
political conditions are ripe. The political obstacles to sound environmental policy
should not be exaggerated. The turning points that have been estimated for different kinds
of pollutants have a tendency to fall within the income range of leading countries at the
time the specific problems became an issue of intense public debate. For example, there
may be nothing special about a turning point for CFC emissions at some $12,000 to $18,000
it just happened to be the income range of the leading countries (which have also
assumed the fastest phase-out commitments) at the time the Montreal Protocol was signed in
1987. And although we find estimates of a turning point for CO2 emissions of up
to several hundred thousand dollars in per capita income, the fact that global warming has
now risen to the forefront of public attention may result in a curbing of emissions at an
earlier date. This will require, however, that countries go from words to actions and
honour their commitments under the Kyoto Agreement. In the end, the environmental Kuznets
curve may not have a "natural" turning point it will turn whenever
political conditions are ripe for delivering the necessary policies to address
environmental
degradation effectively, including through transfers of
resources and technologies to allow developing countries to modernize their production.
Not all kinds of growth are equally benign for
the environment. Economic growth requiring ever more inputs of natural resources is
obviously not as benign for the environment as economic growth driven by technological
progress that saves inputs and reduces emissions per unit of output. This kind of growth
will not necessarily emerge spontaneously, but may require economic incentives that steer
development in a sustainable direction.
Trade could play a positive role. Trade could
play a positive role in this process by facilitating the diffusion of environment-friendly
technologies around the world. Of course, this would require that countries are ready to
scrap trade barriers on modern technologies and suppliers of environmental services to
reduce the cost of investing in clean technologies and environmental management systems. A
new round of trade liberalization negotiations could make a contribution here. Another
potential contribution of such a round would be to address subsidies that harm the
environment, including energy, agricultural and fishing subsides. This would yield a
double dividend by benefitting the environment and the world economy at the same time.
The way forward is multilateral environmental
cooperation. Let us conclude with an observation quoted by Long (1995), which summarizes
the core of the trade and environment debate. During an OECD meeting of Environment
Ministers, one Minister noted that "his country, along with most others, had
committed itself at the 1992 Earth Summit in Rio to the pursuit of sustainable
development. However, whenever he tries to promote the behavioural and technological
changes necessary to move in that direction, i.e., when he attempts to internalise the
costs of environmental pollution and resource degradation, he is branded a 'green
protectionist' outside his country, and a destroyer of national competitiveness at
home."
In short, trade is really not the issue, nor is
economic growth. The issue is how to reinvent environmental polices in an ever more
integrated world economy so as to ensure that we live within ecological limits. The way
forward, it would seem to us, is to strengthen the mechanisms and institutions for
multilateral environmental cooperation, just like countries 50 years ago decided that it
was to their benefit to cooperate on trade matters.
___________________________________________October 1999
|