|
2.5 A Gender Audit
While changes in industrialization strategy in developing
countries have led to increased absorption of women as wage labourers into the modern
sector, there are other questions to be asked as part of an assessment of this job
creation from a gender perspective. Does the proportion of women employed remain high or
fall over time? What happens to gender pay relativities as exports increase and
industrialization proceeds? Have women in those developing countries with the greatest
experience of participation in world markets in manufactures attained a more secure and
beneficial position in the labour market as a result?
Scarcely any research has been done into these questions.
Data limitations make it impossible to give proper answers to these fundamental questions
for any one country, let alone in general. But some observations are relevant.
First, the evidence as to whether or not the demand for
labour in export manufacturing remains female-intensive over time in quantitative terms is
mixed. Wood's (1991) study shows that the high female share in the labour force has
persisted in the large East Asian economies even after diversification. On the other hand,
there are some later, apparent counter-examples which give cause for concern. These relate
to changes in the gender composition of employment in certain EPZs.
EPZs are the epicentre of export manufacturing production
in most developing countries and a strong concentration of women workers is found in them
(see Table 5). With only one exception, they employ much higher proportions of women than
manufacturing enterprises outside EPZs (in the exceptional case, Trinidad and Tobago, EPZ
is a misnomer: the zone is an import processing zone). This paper does not attempt to sort
out employment in export manufacturing as a whole from employment in EPZs and in foreign
enterprises. Overlap within the three categories varies from country to country within the
developing world. No estimates exist of the share of the manufacturing labour force
involved in export production as such (not surprising, since many firms supply domestic as
well as foreign markets); the workforce in EPZs is often taken to stand for the export
manufacturing sector as a whole, but this is not correct, since exporting firms,
especially but not only in Asian countries, are also found outside EPZs in all regions.24
Nevertheless, it is important to understand the reasons
for the fall in the share of women in some EPZs from the very high levels existing
previously. In factories in the Mexican maquiladoras (the EPZ zone along the border with
the United States) the proportion of women employed fell markedly during the 1980s from 77
per cent of the total workforce in 1982 to 60 per cent in 1990 (Baden and Joekes, 1993).
There have also been falls in the share of women in EPZs in Singapore (World Bank, 1992)
and Mauritius (from approximately 80 per cent to 60 per cent over the mid-1980s) (Frisen
and Johansson, 1993; Roberts, 1992.
A cross-country study of EPZs carried out by ILO/UNCTC
hypothesizes that the fall in the share of women workers in EPZs is a general phenomenon
(see Figure 2 reproduced from this source) (ILO/UNCTC, 1988). Given that clothing and
electronics (the main industries) are more female-intensive than other industries, it is
proposed that the share of women workers in EPZs is related to the extent of product
diversification, explaining both variations across countries in the share of women workers
in EPZs and the decline in the share over time in some locations. Figure 3 shows the
general relation between female intensity in the workforce and output composition of EPZs.
Both Mexico and Singapore exemplify their middle-income
status and evolving factor endowment in having relatively high shares of more capital
intensively produced goods in their basket of manufactures exports. In particular, they
have both decreased the share of clothing in their exports to extremely low levels (just
over 2 per cent of total merchandise exports in each case in 1993 (GATT, 1994: Table
III.42) compared to 5-6 per cent in the early 1980s). The falling female share in the
industrial workforce in EPZs in the two cases may thus indeed probably be attributed to
product diversity.
The main form of diversification in the Mexican export
border zone (maquiladoras) has been expansion of automotive assembly for the United States
market. A strong cultural legacy of masculine metal-working means this industry employs
mainly male workers, except in ancillary and finishing positions. The transportation
equipment industry in the maquiladoras employed 33 per cent women workers, compared to
around 80 per cent in electronics and 83 per cent in textiles and garments (ILO/UNCTC,
1988:66). But Mexico is unique among developing countries in having a long land border
with a major rich country market, which favours bulky exports. Auto assembly may not
flourish elsewhere.
Along with the Republic of Korea and Taiwan Province of
China, Singapore has pursued its goal of product upgrading and deepening of the employment
structure through a concerted policy of investment in technology and skills, through
technology inflows (in capital goods imports, high technology foreign investment, and
technical co-operation) and expansion of education in science and technology.25 Singapore's remarkably high share of R&D in gross domestic
investment (29 per cent, which far outstrips the rate in any other Asian developing
country) (Lall, 1994:20) and the extremely high proportion of manufacturing employment
provided by TNC affiliates (58 per cent) (United Nations, 1994) are other aspects of this
policy.
While the gender gap in education in East Asian countries,
including Singapore, is generally not large compared to other regions, gender disparities
are evident in an enrolment gap at tertiary level and in the mix of courses and subjects
taken by male and female students at this level. There is a strong bias towards science
and technology subjects among male students. The swing back from female intensity in
Singaporean manufacturing may thus be attributable, as a proximate cause, to the fact that
women workers with the requisite technical qualifications are not available for
recruitment to new technical and other skilled grades, because relatively few women have
had access to the necessary subject education. More information is needed on the gender
composition of employment in these grades, which to be equitably staffed we would expect
to see employ 40-50 per cent women in keeping with the gender composition of the total
labour force. The extreme female-labour intensity of employment in assembly-type
operations is, as we have seen, a symptom of women's inferiority in the labour market and
a swing towards more balanced representation would not necessarily be a negative
development. As will be seen in Section 4.2, there is some evidence that in the East Asian
region women do have a strong presence in scientific and technical positions in some
countries in the information processing industry and in some branches of services.
The Mauritian case is quite different from Mexico and
Singapore. The fall in the share of women cannot be explained by product diversification
and changes in the factor intensity of production or skill mix of employment. There has
been no output diversification, indeed the dominance of the clothing industry has
increased (accounting for 89 per cent of EPZ production in 1990). The fall in the share of
female workers has been attributed to a combination of factors: the exhaustion of the
local female labour supply, the introduction of shift working to improve plant utilization
levels (but without changes in technology or production methods) and the abolition of the
male minimum wage (previously set higher than the female wage rate) (Frisen and Johansson,
1993).
Employers' preference for female labour is unproblematic
where the unemployment rate is much higher among women than men (as in most Latin American
countries, see United Nations, 1995) or where the general labour supply situation is
generally tight (as in East Asian countries). In some other cases, employers' exercise of
preference for female labour at lower rates of pay has been a cause of severe social
tension. When male unemployment rates are very high, pressures arise for men to be given
access to such jobs as are available, invoking aspects of gender identity such as the
"male breadwinner" ethic. Such pressures were in evidence in the Dominican
Republic in the mid-1980s in areas where men were dismissed in large numbers from the
failing sugar industry. Employers were at that time resisting this pressure more
exactly, they were prepared to recruit men but only at the prevailing rate of pay, which
men refused to accept without an additional "male worker" premium, despite their
high rates of unemployment (Joekes, 1987). It is reported that the Mauritian government
was persuaded to drop the high legal minimum wage for male workers because of men's
hostility to the exclusive access to modern sector jobs given to women in EPZs (Frisen and
Johansson 1993; Roberts 1992). It is a positive development here from a gender perspective
that men have taken work, apparently without a wage premium.26
How far do falling shares of women workers in EPZs
undermine the female-intensive export industrialization thesis? There is no necessary
inconsistency in the short term. If the export orientation pioneered in EPZs spreads to
the rest of the economy, and newly exporting firms outside EPZs employ female labour while
EPZs move away from the extreme female intensity displayed in their early days, the gap
between female labour shares in EPZs and non-EPZs illustrated in Table 5 will be narrowed
from both sides, with the overall sectoral trend continuing upwards.
But if non-EPZ firms also follow EPZs in due course and
move to shift working, change the skill mix of employment (without training existing
female employees and moving them up the job grade hierarchy) and so on, then the female
share in the sectoral labour force may peak at a certain point. If women's employment
proves to be confined to technologically low grade parts of industry, and change in the
composition of the labour force in EPZs is a harbinger of gendered labour demand patterns
elsewhere, indicating failure on the state's part to provide gender balance in educational
provision and on employers' part to train women employees to higher level work, we may
indeed be in a historically limited phase of the mobilization of female labour, with no
consolidation of women's position in the labour market thereafter.
We move on now from investigating changes over time in the
quantity of trade-related employment open to women to consider the issue of the quality of
trade-related employment, including pay. The issue can be broken down into two parts. The
first concerns cross-sectional evidence about the nature of women's employment in
trade-related activities, compared to non-exporting activities; and the second relates to
hypotheses about likely changes over time in the relative wages in the export sector
compared to other activities and gender differentials in pay within the sector.
At the most general level, it is clear that new employment
options in manufacturing represent a significantly better opportunity for women than the
alternatives, especially but not only in the least developed countries. Physical working
conditions are generally better in the modern industrial sector than in the informal
sector, in terms of levels of dust, heat, light, and noise, with the biggest enterprises
providing the best conditions (World Bank, 1992; ILO/UNCTC, 1985). Nevertheless,
high-level health hazards exist in some activities, e.g. use of carcinogenic substances
and risk of eyestrain in electronics and micro-circuitry production, which have not been
adequately assessed. The literature also contains many accounts of the physical hardships
entailed for factory women working extremely long hours under arduous conditions (Baden
and Joekes, 1993), with no discretion over the timing or extent of work.
With respect to earnings, there is little doubt that even
the worst paid factory jobs are a better alternative for women to low or unpaid work in
the agricultural sector and to the poorly paid, usually non-contractual, work in urban
areas to which their income earning opportunities are otherwise limited (ILO/UNCTC, 1985;
Joekes and Weston, 1994). Whether women consider that the extra pay is more than
sufficient compensation for the demanding conditions of factory work is another question
on which the literature is mixed.
But a proper assessment of the effects of trade expansion
requires evidence of employment conditions in trade-related compared to other employment
within the manufacturing sector which is not available. There is information, as before,
on the situation in TNCs and in EPZs compared with other firms, although, as noted,
neither of these is necessarily a good proxy for the manufacturing export sector.
Within the manufacturing sector TNCs pay marginally higher
wages than local firms, in both developed and developing countries (UNCTAD, 1992) and
there is no reason to think that exporting TNCs do not conform. Several reasons are
advanced to explain this: the occupational mix often differs between TNCs and local firms
(the wage comparison should be adjusted to take account of this, but data do not allow
it); TNCs are larger than the average firm; high product quality requirements in
export-oriented firms lead the TNC employer to be prepared to pay a wage premium to
workers skilled in particular operational methods to retain their loyalty (another
application of the efficiency wage argument); and finally, political caution leads TNCs to
wish to stand as good employers, above local criticism (ibid.).
If there is any concentration in women's employment
opportunities in TNCs, then, and taking employment in TNCs as trade-related in the
broadest sense, trade-related employment may give access to relatively good jobs for
women. Whether this extends to improvement in pay differentials by gender is not known. On
the one hand, for political reasons TNCs might be expected to observe equal wage
legislation more punctiliously than local firms, where equal wage legislation exists. On
the other, TNCs are merely incrementally "better practice" employers; it would
be surprising if they countered labour market norms to the extent of ignoring the cost
advantages presented to them by the prevailing gap in wage levels by gender and paid more
equal wages to female employees than do local firms, even where equal pay conventions
exist, and certainly not where they do not.27
Information on employment practices and relative wages in
EPZs has some limited relevance. Much research into employment conditions and pay in EPZs
has been done, from widely varying perspectives. The feminist literature tends to
concentrate on employment terms and conditions, but usually from an absolutist position,
i.e., neglecting any comparison with conditions in non-EPZ firms. Equally
unsatisfactorily, research into relative wages between EPZ and non-EPZ firms takes an
aggregate view, but mostly ignores the gender dimension.
As regards, first, overall wage relativities in EPZ firms
compared to non-EPZ firms in manufacturing, some sources (e.g. World Bank, 1992) assert
that wages in EPZs are uniformly higher. But counter-cases certainly exist, e.g. in India
and Mauritius, where wages are "definitely lower than in the surrounding national
economy" (Starnberg Institute, cited in Baden and Joekes, 1993:15). This conforms to
the idea of an EPZ "salary life cycle" as proposed by ILO/UNCTC: "in its
early days, an EPZ generally offers wages which are slightly higher than other local
wages. As the EPZ develops the wage differential gradually decreases and after 10 or 15
years it is not infrequent to observe that wages in EPZ industries are somewhat lower than
other local wages" (ILO/UNCTC, 1988:102).
Such assessments of comparative wages ought to be adjusted
for differences in the gender composition of workforce inside and outside EPZs, given
prevailing gender gaps in wages in manufacturing (Baden and Joekes, 1993). If, however,
the gender composition of the respective workforces remains constant over time28 this suggests a secular decline in earnings for women relative to
men. The fall in the female: male pay ratio over the 1980s in Sri Lanka (see Table 2) may
reflect this, because in this case EPZs account for a significant proportion of total
manufacturing sector employment (27 per cent in 1987) and 88 per cent of EPZ workers were
women. If however, the female share of the EPZ workforce rises over time, this would in
itself account for some of the relative decline in average wages. The question remains
open.
The very high share of women currently in EPZs makes
direct investigation of gender pay relativities inside EPZ firms problematic: occupational
segregation may be so complete that, for instance, no men may be employed in the
line-operative positions occupied by women. The few case studies of EPZ employment that
address gender differences in pay nevertheless all report systematic underpayment of women
workers compared to men, where they work in similar jobs. In some countries there is
statutory provision for all firms, including those in EPZs, to pay women less than men; in
other cases, such as Mauritius, Korea, Malaysia, Taiwan Province of China and the
Dominican Republic, payment of overtly lower wage rates for women is recorded (Baden and
Joekes, 1993). The only indication that EPZ employers might prove themselves better
employers than the norm in gender terms, and challenge prevailing gender inequalities in
pay, comes from the Dominican Republic but, as noted, by attempting to level down
men's wages rather than levelling up women's.
The last piece of anecdotal evidence relevant to pay
relativities in trade-related employment comes from the new, rapidly expanding clothing
industry Bangladesh. The wage gap by gender is extremely small in this case, with the
female:male ratio in wages almost unity (0.97) (see Section 4). A female labour force has
been mobilized with great speed in circumstances where wage employment for women outside
agriculture was previously virtually non-existent.29 One
interpretation of the situation is that in order to create the kind of (female) workforce
that experience in other countries suggests they will find most satisfactory, employers
have offered women high start-up wages, on a par with male wages, even in the virtual
absence of other opportunities in the modern sector, and with great gender disparities in
income elsewhere in the economy. If this "kick-start" hypothesis is correct,
employers may begin to exploit women's vulnerable labour market position once a female
labour supply is established, and, as in agriculture, pay female wages below the male
rate.
Moving now to changes in pay relativities over time, the
first point to be made is that there is a clear prediction from international trade theory
that over the long run trade will raise aggregate incomes and wages in developing
countries. There is no doubt that incomes and wages in the export-oriented East Asian
miracle countries have risen spectacularly over a relatively short time, and given their
weight as exporters, that a statistical correlation exists between trade and wage
increases. The micro-level mechanisms which might bring about this outcome, and more
precisely how wages move in exporting firms compared to others, and the gender dimension
of these changes, have not been researched.
The export sector may or may not prove to be a leading
wage sector and may or may not affect the gender wage differential. If the export sector
expands rapidly with high profitability as a price taker in world markets, then there may
be scope for workers to share in the profits, and employers may be prepared to pay a wage
premium to secure the best workers and retain their loyalty. Such a tendency might cover
both increases in the average wage in manufacturing and in the female:male wage ratio, to
the extent that women are concentrated in the export sector and there is a spillover
effect which raises the level of wages women expect in other sectors (holding female
labour supply conditions constant).
On the other hand, if producers' competitiveness is
threatened, or market conditions are uncertain for cyclical or other reasons, exporters
may look to ways of cutting costs especially of labour, and especially perhaps of
female labour and thus, other things being equal, increase the gender wage gap.
Another way of addressing the possibility of changes in
the wage gap can be derived from a simple model of dual (male and female) labour markets.
In a trade-expansionary context the demand for female labour increases faster than for
male labour, so that female wages also rise relatively fast and there is a tendency to
"convergence" between female and male wages over time. But the world is not
simple and many complicating factors could exist. Female labour supply might increase so
rapidly that it offsets any tendency for employers to offer higher wages to women; the
composition of the female labour force might change over time to include larger numbers of
those groups (e.g. older, married women, as discussed above, or female heads of household)
prepared to accept low relative wages, for reasons to do with the nature of the conjugal
contract. Finally, the boundaries between male and female segments of the labour market
are not fixed. It is clear that in other contexts the gender division of labour is revised
in response to changing circumstances, though the fact of division persists (e.g. with
respect to environmental change, see Leach, Green and Joekes, 1995). In the labour market
context, redefinition of the segments certainly does take place, in terms of changing
stereotyping of male and female jobs (Barbezat, 1993). The systematic shift away from
recruiting women with changes in the skill composition of employment, discussed above,
could be interpreted as a means for ensuring that excess labour supply conditions are
maintained in the low wage female segment, countering any movement towards convergence of
wages by gender.
The empirical testing of these various possibilities
remains to be done. The only study carried out so far is by Tzannatos (1995),30 which deals with very general question of changes in women's
earnings over time with economic growth. Information is given on changes in relative wages
for female and male workers over the 1980s at both national and sectoral levels for six
countries (Côte d'Ivoire, Brazil, Colombia, Philippines, Thailand and Indonesia). The
results are reproduced in Table 6. Relative wages for women have risen steadily in all
cases, with reductions in the gender wage ratio ranging between 4.5 per cent points
(Colombia) to 12.8 percentage points (Philippines). Tzannatos interprets his findings very
positively, suggesting that women's labour market situation may be improving in developing
countries in the contemporary period much faster than it did historically in the developed
countries. The data do not allow the role of trade expansion in the process to be examined
rigorously. Women in the two countries where export growth has been particularly rapid
(Thailand and Indonesia) have shared in this outcome, but their performance is not
exceptional.
The sources of this improvement are identified and vary
between countries. Indonesia and Thailand are distinctive for the fact that reduction in
the wage gap attributable to changes in the sectoral distribution of women's employment in
favour of higher paying sectors (i.e., manufacturing) has been the highest. That the
largest sectoral shift in female employment towards manufacturing should be found in the
two most export-oriented countries in the sample is quite consistent with the argument of
this paper. The increase in the share of the female labour force in manufacturing has been
associated with only a very small increase in women's relative earnings within the sector
in Indonesia, and a somewhat larger increase in Thailand. This suggests that wages may be
higher in the export sector within manufacturing, compared to other branches of
manufacturing where women are employed, to a small extent in Indonesia, and more
significantly in Thailand.
In any event, data on other countries, presented in Tables
3 and 7, though not exactly comparable, do not fully bear out his findings. Table 3 gives
data on female:male earnings in manufacturing (the figure of most interest to the argument
presented in this paper) for a number of developing countries in different regions which
show that there is no trend towards amelioration over time, most especially not in Hong
Kong, Singapore or the Republic of Korea. Indeed, at the national level the Republic of
Korea has the largest gender gap in wages on record. Table 7 presents national level data,
such as Tzannatos uses. Among the 15 developing countries for which time series data are
given, 10 show a rise in the ratio but four show a fall, and one shows no change.
Two lessons can be drawn from this. The first is that
clearly more research is necessary on this crucial topic. The second is that the crude
data, but also Tzannatos' analysis, do not take account of an important parametric change.
The relative educational levels of the female population, who represent the pool from
which female labour is drawn, has been rising in most countries outside Africa (see the
forthcoming UNDP Human Development Report 1995). In particular, the marked rise in female
wages in the Philippines reported in Table 6 may be attributable to the very strong
increase in women's educational attainments in that country (for instance, women's
enrolment rate at secondary level is now higher than men's (World Development Report,
1993). That is to say, there should in any event be greater parity in women's earnings in
the economy as a whole and in manufacturing in particular, with increases in educational
levels. Slight rises in the female:male wage ratio might have to be discounted for this
reason. The proper index, in other words, for which changes over time and the possible
effects of trade expansion need to be investigated is the degree of wage discrimination to
which women are subject.
24 The literature on gender aspects of EPZ employment is reviewed in Baden and
Joekes, 1993. Wood's cross-country analysis of the causes female intensity in
manufacturing employment overall, reported in section 2.4, used national level
manufacturing sector data from ILO sources in investigating the feminization of the
manufacturing labour force, the statistically proper measure.
25 Singapore, Taiwan Province of China and the Republic of Korea have total
enrolment rates in science and technology subjects at university/college level of the
order of 50 per cent higher than in Latin America and about five times higher than Egypt,
which has the highest rates in Africa (United Nations, 1992: Table III-3).
26 Barbezat (1993) discusses the factors determining change-overs in the gender
composition of the workforce by occupation, with respect to issues of the relative length
of labour queues among each gender, customary gender biases, etc., similarly to those
suggested as relevant here. But the theoretical literature, which is in any case
inconclusive as to causation, discusses only developed country circumstances and is
confined almost entirely to cases of switching from male to female employment, not the
reverse.
27 The concluding section of the paper suggests that there may be some scope for
advocacy and international action to influence TNCs' employment practices for the better,
especially in settings where equal wage legislation exists.
28 Though, as discussed above, this situation may not obtain.
29 Haiti may be a similar case. The ratio of female:male wages was unusually high
(0.87; see Table 4), in a situation where almost the only wage employment available to
women was in the short-lived export manufacturing sector, largely producing baseballs for
the US market.
30 Also by report an unpublished study by Susan Horton of the University of
Toronto, Canada, not available to the author at the time of writing.
|