|
Transition and the Changing Role of Government
Vito Tanzi
Over the past decade, many centrally planned economies have set out to transform
themselves into market economies. To be successful, they need to develop the necessary
institutions and ensure a proper role for government.
While much has been written about the economic changes that must take place for
centrally planned countries to become market economies, less has been written about how
the economic role of the state must change. In "shock therapy," advocated by
some economists at the start of the transition, the main ingredients for success were
assumed to be price liberalization, macroeconomic stabilization, and privatization. Little
was said about the role of the government in the new environment. A complete
transformation of the economy, the institutions, and economic processes requires, in
addition, that
- profitability be the guiding criterion for most investment decisions;
- activities deemed socially desirable be financed by the government; and
- the government effectively perform its core functions in the economy while withdrawing
from, or drastically reducing its role in, many secondary activities.
Elements of a market economy
To function well, market economies need governments that can establish and enforce the
"rules of the game," promote widely shared social objectives, raise revenues to
finance public sector activities, spend the revenues productively, enforce contracts and
protect property, and produce public goods. They also need a pared-down set of regulations
that are clear and leave little margin for interpretation or discretion. While the guiding
principle under central planning was that nothing was permitted unless explicitly
authorized, the guiding principle in a market economy should be that everything is
permitted unless expressly forbidden.
The transformation to a market economy is not complete until functioning fiscal
institutions and reasonable and affordable expenditure programs, including basic social
safety nets for the unemployed, the sick, and the elderly, are in place. Spending programs
must be financed from public revenues generatedthrough taxationwithout
imposing excessive burdens on the private sector. Because the level of taxation of a
country depends on, among other criteria, the extent of its economic development and the
sophistication of its tax systems and administration, these constraints must be considered
in discussions of public spending.
Finally, because the optimal role for government derives not just from economic
considerations but also from the interplay of political and economic forces, the views of
the executive branch of government should broadly match those of the legislative branch.
If the two sides are miles apart on what the government should do, as they have been in
Russia and some other countries, neither an optimal government role nor rational policies
are likely to emerge.
Institutions in a market economy
To perform their tasks, governments in market economies need some well-developed
institutions run by competent individuals and guided by appropriate incentives. The
objectives of the managers must not diverge from those of the institutions, which must in
turn be consistent with the public interest. Such institutions do not materialize
magically. They need to be created and continually reformed. In industrial countries, it
took centuries for these institutions to evolve.
When the necessary public institutions do not exist or, if they do exist, when the
incentives for their managers are perverse, the government can easily become an impediment
to economic activity because it ends up being used by individuals for their own ends. This
is what normally happens in a corrupt system, where parts of the government apparatus are
privatized for the gains of individuals or special interest groups. In such a system, the
achievement of social objectives is difficult and some of the government's actions may
appear predatory, such as when state employees extract bribes from citizens who need
permits or authorizations.
Pre-transition environment
At the beginning of the transition, the share of GDP derived from private sector
activities was small in all transition countries. It ranged from less than 1 percent in
the former Czechoslovakia and Russia to almost 20 percent in Poland, compared with about
80 percent in the United States. Economic production occurred overwhelmingly in the public
sector because few productive assets could be privately owned and few private activities
were allowed. Prices and genuine economic profits did not play much of a role in resource
allocation because the use of resources was determined by political decisions made within
the planning office.
The transition countries did not need market-type tax systems to raise public revenues
because the government decided how to use total output and could simply appropriate
production for its own needs. Taxes were mostly transfers from some activities to others.
The primary function of tax administrators was to ensure that funds were transferred to
the government books and accounted for. There was no budget office, no budget law, and no
treasury.
Tax revenues were obtained from three major sourcesturnover taxes, taxes on
enterprises, and payroll taxeswhich generated large revenues (at times up to 50
percent of GDP). Under this system, most taxes were hidden, so that individuals were
largely unaware that, indirectly, they were paying high taxes. Taxes were collected on the
basis of negotiations with government officials. The government was free to change the
rates and changed them often; when it needed extra revenue, it negotiated to raise more
taxes. An enterprise in difficulty might negotiate to lower its taxes.
Particular characteristics of central planning made tax collection relatively simple:
(1) the authorities' knowledgeavailable from the planof quantities of goods
produced and of the prices at which they would be sold; (2) the role of the central bank
in processing payments and imposing restrictions on how payments were to be settled; and
(3) the concentration of economic activities in a few large enterprises. Well-defined or
fixed rules of law that individuals or enterprises could appeal to when they disagreed
with the actions of the government did not exist.
Progress in general reforms
How much progress have the former socialist countries made in transforming their
economies? Evaluating them on the basis of the shock-therapy approach gives the impression
that progress has been considerable. In general, the Eastern European and Baltic countries
have progressed rapidly, while the other countries have been less successful in
establishing fiscal institutions, controlling fiscal imbalances, and redefining the role
of the state. But even within these groups, the differences are significant (see table
below). In some countries, one senses that the old system is largely gone but that nothing
has taken its place, leaving an institutional vacuum.
Progress in transition, 1998
|
|
Private
sector
share of GDP |
Enterprises2
|
Markets
and trade2 |
Financial
institutions2
Banking reform |
|
(percent,
mid-1998)1 |
Large-scale
privatization |
Small-scale
privatization |
Price
liberalization |
and
interest rate
liberalization |
|
Albania
Armenia
Azerbaijan
Belarus
Bulgaria
|
75
60
45
20
50
|
2
3
2
1
3
|
4
3
3
2
3
|
3
3
3
2
3
|
2
2+
2
1
3
|
|
Croatia
Czech Republic
Estonia
Georgia
Hungary
|
55
75
70
60
80
|
3
4
4
3+
4
|
4+
4+
4+
4
4+
|
3
3
3
3
3+
|
3
3
3+
2+
4
|
|
Kazakhstan
Kyrgyz Republic
Latvia
Lithuania
Moldova
|
55
60
60
70
45
|
3
3
3
3
3
|
4
4
4
4
3+
|
3
3
3
3
3
|
2+
3
3
3
2+
|
|
Poland
Romania
Russian Federation
Slovak Republic
Tajikistan
|
65
60
70
75
30
|
3+
3
3+
4
2
|
4+
3+
4
4+
2+
|
3+
3
3
3
3
|
3+
2+
2
3
1
|
|
Turkmenistan
Ukraine
Uzbekistan
|
25
55
45
|
2
2+
3
|
2
3+
3
|
2
3
2
|
1
2
2
|
|
Source:
European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, Transition Report, 1998, Table
2.1. 1 Private sector shares of GDP represent rough EBRD estimates,
based on available statistics from both official (government) and unofficial sources. The
underlying concept of private sector value added includes income generated by the activity
of private registered companies, as well as by private entities engaged in informal
activity, in those cases where reliable information on informal activity is available.
2 The numerical indicators range from 1 to 4, with 1 representing the least
progress. They are intended to represent cumulative progress in the movement from a
centrally planned economy to a market economy in each dimension, rather than the rate of
change in the course of the year. |
|
Privatization. The private sector share in GDP, almost insignificant 10 years
ago, has risen dramatically in many transition countries, reaching 70 percent or more in
Albania, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Lithuania, Russia, and the Slovak Republic.
Only in Belarus, Tajikistan, and Turkmenistan does it remain at 30 percent or lower. While
impressive, these percentages reflect privatization of ownership but not necessarily of
management. In many countries, either the prereform managers are still running the
enterprises or the new managers behave as if the enterprises were still owned by the
state.
One intriguing aspect of the privatization experience in these countries is that, as
state ownership has declined, the rise in fiscal proceeds from privatization has not been
commensurate. Although the state owned almost everything before the transition, the
revenues it collected from the sale of its assets were minuscule. In Russia, for example,
assets valued at $5060 billion were reportedly bought for $1.5 billion.
There are several reasons for the low revenues. Privatization was tantamount to a fire
sale to which only a privileged few were invited, and they used their positions or
connections to amass enormous wealth. Thus, although constituting a fundamental step
toward a market economy, privatization became an obstacle to the protection of private
propertyanother prerequisite of a market economy.
Nomenklatura privatizationthe purchase of state enterprises by former high
officials of the communist partyand other similar developments, such as the purchase
at low prices of valuable assets of state enterprises, have contributed to the dramatic
changes in the distribution of income in these countries. Before the transition, they had
some of the most even income distributions in the world, a source of pride for their
leaders. Within a few years, however, some of the richest men and women in the
worldsome of whom also acquired substantial political powerwere living a life
of conspicuous consumption. More worrisome is the increase in inequality that has
occurred, not because individuals who rose higher on the income scale created wealth but
because they raided the government's wealth.
It is easy to guess the reaction of these countries' populations to the economic
changes that created these new circumstances and to understand why the market economy,
which is identified with these changes, is blamed. Many of the measures necessary to make
a market economy vibrant and efficient will be seen as protecting the ill-gotten wealth of
the new upper class and will encounter difficulty in the political process. It should not
be surprising if privatization is not universally accepted as a sign of progress.
Price liberalization. The transition countries as a group have gone far toward
liberalizing and stabilizing prices (see table). Although Belarus, Tajikistan, and
Uzbekistan show little progress, most countries show some, and a fewHungary and
Polandshow a great deal. However, freeing prices on some goods does not ensure
increased efficiency if prices remain controlled in large and vital sectors such as
energy.
Fiscal reforms. Most transition economies have implemented major fiscal reforms
in the 1990s, some more successfully than others. Because a tax culture never developed in
the centrally planned economies, people reacted with hostility to the introduction of an
explicit tax system.
The economic reforms that took place in these countries at the beginning of the
transition had a damaging impact on the existing public finances.
- They destroyed the plan, thus eliminating the information (good or bad) on quantities of
goods produced and on prices. The government had to rely on other sources, including
taxpayers' declarations, for this information. Tax evasion increased.
- They increased dramatically the number of producers and thus the number of potential
taxpayers, as private sector activities came into existence. Tax administrations that had
been used to dealing with relatively few, friendly enterprises had to deal with hundreds
of thousands, or even millions, of unfriendly taxpayers. Large state enterprises, which
had provided the bulk of tax revenue, declined in importance, while new small and
difficult-to-tax private producers emerged as the most dynamic sector of the economy. They
required both close attention from tax authorities, because of their propensity to evade
taxes, and protection from unscrupulous tax officials.
- They removed the restrictions on payment methods that had existed under central planning
(when all payments were channeled through the central bank). Unfortunately, tax arrears
and payments in the form of barter have grown, creating major difficulties for the new
system.
Because of these changes, among others, the old systems could not easily be reformed.
Totally new systems were needed, and they required not just new tax laws but also new
fiscal institutions, new skills, technical knowledge, and political capital. Few of the
transition economies have been able to meet these requirements of a market-oriented
system.
Many countries attempted to patch up the old institutions to make them behave like new
ones. The poorly paid personnel of these institutions, schooled in the old ways, were
often the main obstacle to change, and those who were put in charge of these institutions
often had limited knowledge of how tax administrations should work in market economies.
Their incentive was to maintain the old system. It would have been far better to create,
from scratch, new institutions.
Many governments have failed to accept or understand that, in a market economy, a tax
system should be based on laws that establish tax rates and rules for objectively defining
the tax bases and should have one paramount objectiveto raise revenue as efficiently
and equitably as possible. Rather, these governments view the tax system as a tool that
should do many thingskeep failing enterprises alive, sustain employment by allowing
loss-making enterprises to pay wages instead of taxes, stimulate economic activity, and so
on. In some ways, the tax system replaced the plan as the key instrument for economic and
social policy. Thus, in some of these countries, taxes have continued to be soft and
discretionary, and key ministers have continued to spend more time dealing with individual
taxpayers' tax problems than reforming the tax system. This may have sharply increased the
tax burden on segments of the economy that are not able to receive preferential treatment.
In many of these countries, especially the larger ones, public spending has remained
very high as a share of GDP. Once made, spending plans may be difficult to revise,
especially downward. This is particularly true of pensions, health benefits, and public
employment, which involve long-term commitments. One reason for many countries' high
ratios of spending to GDP is that they have experienced declines in output. Another is
that they have not yet formulated policies for shrinking the role of the state. The
government remains engaged in far too many activities.
Conclusion
Major changes will need to occur to complete the transition. Changes can be either
superficialessentially those envisaged by the shock-therapy approachor deep,
including creation of new institutions, changes in incentives, changes in processes, and
transformation of the role of government. These deep changes are much more difficult and
time-consuming because they involve structural reforms and require a major modification of
attitudes, incentives, and relationships.
Once a country has made the transition to a market economy, the role of government is
dramatically different. It operates not through direct controls but mostly through the tax
system, the budget, and a few essential regulations. The tax system must be totally
reformed to make it efficient and equitable and capable of raising reasonable revenues.
Expenditure policies must be brought in line with the reduced public resources. The new
regulations will play a role in setting the rules of the game, regulating private
pensions, and enforcing competition. Most permits, authorizations, and other mechanisms
that are known to promote bribery must be eliminated, because they lead to the corruption
that is widespread in many transition economies.
Given the decline in income equality in these countries and their experiences with
privatization, it is likely that their governments will be asked to play a more positive
role in income redistribution. Policymakers should work hard to harmonize the concept of
the role of the state that seems to prevail in many of their legislatures with one that is
feasible, given the existing macroeconomic conditions and level of institutional and
economic development.
There must be a fuller realization that, while large fiscal deficits are often a
macroeconomic problem, they become a more fundamental problem when they force governments
to renege on their legal contracts by sequestering or freezing payments across the board.
These actions are a corruption of the budgetary process and the market economy. When a
public employee is not paid or when pensioners do not receive pensions to which they are
legally entitled, something is fundamentally wrong with the whole political budgetary
process.
Suggestions for further reading:
Lajos Bokros and Jean-Jacques Dethier, eds., 1998, Public Finance
Reform During the Transition: The Experience of Hungary (Washington: World Bank).
Adrienne Cheasty and Jeffrey Davis, 1996, "Fiscal Transition in
Countries of the Former Soviet Union: An Interim Assessment," MOCT-MOST: Economic
Policy in Transitional Economies (Netherlands), Vol. 6, pp. 734.
European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1998, Transition
Report, 1998 (London).
Vito Tanzi, 1992, Fiscal Policies in Economies in Transition (Washington:
International Monetary Fund).
Vito Tanzi is Director of the
IMF's Fiscal Affairs Department. |
|