Taken from http://www.duke.edu/literature/dependency.htm
The published version of this paper appears in the internet journal Cultural Logic, vol. 1, no. 2 (1998). A much shorter
version was presented at a panel on post-marxist aporias at the Modern Language
Association Annual Meeting in 1998. I am grateful to David Siar for inviting me to be on
that panel, and for publishing the expanded version in Cultural Logic.
DEPENDENCY THEORY'S REANIMATION
IN THE ERA OF FINANCIAL CAPITAL
Kenneth Surin
There is now virtual unanimity about the causes and
character of the demise of capitalism's so-called 'Golden Age', i.e. the prolonged
expansion associated with high employment, growing wages and welfare expenditures, high
consumption, and benign business cycles that lasted in the advanced industrial countries
from 1945 to 1973, and which effectively ended when the quadrupling of oil prices in that
year threw most of the world's economies into recession.(1) Of course the
precise nature of the complex amalgam of economic, political, social, and cultural
transformations involved in this epochal shift from the 'Golden Age' to its successor
'Leaden Age' (to use a term of Robert Pollin's) is a matter of considerable debate among
students of political economy, and these include many who reflect on the character and
import of marxian or marxisante accounts of capitalist development. These reflections on
the transition from the 'Golden' to the 'Leaden Age' are carried out under the now
well-known titles 'late capitalism', 'advanced capitalism', 'disorganized capitalism',
'deregulatory capitalism', 'actually existing world capitalism', 'integrated world
capitalism', 'postFordism', 'postindustrialization', 'overconsumptionist economic
regimes', and so forth. The deliverances of such reflection have profound implications for
any understanding of the forces and structures associated with uneven development, late
industrialization and 'peripheralization'-- all these being notions vital to the
explanations and theories of systemic international inequality sponsored by the various
marxist traditions. (I am well-aware of the arguments of those who maintain that it is not
clear that the global economy has in fact undergone the transformations it is alleged to
have by those who invoke such titles and their accompanying notions, and that, to the
contrary, there has not in fact been any kind of move towards a more 'open'
international economy. Unfortunately, nearly all these arguments focus on the movements of
productive and nonportfolio investment capital and hence do not account for
burgeoning of extraterritorial markets in portfolio capital that has taken place in the
last decade in particular, an expansion which is the specific focus of my argument.(2))
I. On Retaining the Dependency Paradigm
In this paper I examine the claim, advanced in many
quarters and in several versions, that the most recent forms of capitalist development
have effectively discredited theories of uneven or dependent development, and this because
these theories hinge crucially on conceptions that are no longer plausible theoretically
and which have been sidelined by recent historical events. Thus, the ending of the 'Golden
Age' ensued in a radical restructuring of world capitalism that saw the emergence of new
regimes of international competition. These new regimes have caused many so-called Third
World countries to lurch into protracted recession and the associated problems of chronic
debt and current account imbalances. At the same time these low-income countries have had
to face the foreclosure of any real alternative to complete assimilation into the
capitalist system of production, especially since the only apparent alternative to
capitalism-- the 'actually existing socialism' of the former eastern bloc-- has fallen
into desuetude since 1989 (if not before). However, while the majority of peripheral and
semiperipheral countries have not benefited from the regime of accumulation that has
superseded that of the 'Golden Age', the countries of East Asia have until recently been
able to advance economically, thereby controverting a major tenet of the dependencia
school. With the significant advance of the East Asian countries, it was no longer
possible to maintain a hard-and-fast distinction between 'core', 'semiperipheral' and
'peripheral' nations (if indeed this was ever really possible), and to insist that
dependency is an ineluctable condition for nations not initially situated inside the
capitalist 'core', that the very constitution of the 'core' required other national
economies to exist in a state of economic subordination.
At a more purely theoretical level, critiques have
also been made of the various 'essentialisms' and false 'universalisms' that are said to
bedevil the development or dependency paradigms. Examples of these include the presumption
that industrialization and the possession of industrial capital are the crucial requisites
of economic progress (so that an economy is deemed to be developed, developing, or
undeveloped depending on whether or not it has traversed an appropriate path to
industrialization, and thus to have amassed a commensurate kind and scale of industrial
capital); the inability to think beyond the state as the primary and essential vehicle of
economic development; the (often unacknowledged) importation of problematic assumptions
regarding the role of foreign investment and foreign trade in the so-called less developed
economies; a eurocentric bias; an overlooking or deemphasizing of production undertaken by
women; and an underestimation of the implications of widespread and haphazard industrial
development for the environment.(3) In the face of
these and other challenges to their paradigm, the proponents of theories of uneven
development or dependency have, according to their critics, done little more than
reiterate (i) their conviction that some form of socialism can still function as a
potential countervailing force to capitalist depredation, and (ii) their belief in the
efficacy of some kind of strategic decoupling of the less-developed economies from the
capitalist world-system, again with the hope that this can function as a protection
against capitalist encroachment. But, say these critics, neither (i) nor (ii) appear to be
viable in the current capitalist dispensation. This dispensation is more staunchly and
comprehensively inhospitable to socialist aspirations than it has ever been (thereby
blocking-off any socialist path to socialism). Moreover, the completely integrated
character of actually existing world capitalism ostensibly makes any attempt at decoupling
a sure-fire recipe for economic collapse or extinction.
In examining this claim, or set of claims, I want
to suggest that there is a good case to be made for the retention of notions of uneven
development and dependency, albeit ones framed in very different terms. After all,
persistent international economic inequalities remain, and if anything are becoming even
more intractable; and the problems of chronic debt and pervasive international market
instability are still around, as is apparent in the current East Asian crisis and in the
plight of nearly every sub-Saharan nation since the 1970s. And, furthermore, at a
theoretical level, the last decade or so has seen several compelling attempts on the part
of dependency theorists to rid their formulations of the above-mentioned 'essentialisms'
and false universalisms, and especially to think of the developmental state in other than
purely mechanistic or monolithic terms.(4) I shall not
however engage specifically with any of these attempts at reformulation, convincing though
I find many of them to be. Rather, my goal is to arrive at a version of dependency theory
through the construction of an account of the impact, both economic and political, of
transnational financial capital on the so-called less developed economies-- the impact of
global financial markets being a phenomenon not usually taken into consideration by
proponents of the theory of uneven development, and this primarily because
underdevelopment has tended to be viewed primarily in terms of a country's flawed or
incomplete negotiation of the processes of industrialization, and also because the
large-scale effects of a whole range of new global financial markets on less developed
economies have been felt only fairly recently (and primarily within the last decade at
that), thus making it difficult for them to be registered by all but the most current
analyses of underdevelopment and dependency.
With this objective in mind, I take the dependency
or uneven development paradigm essentially to involve assent to some version of each of
the following related propositions:
1. Disparities in wealth between nations as a group
are due fundamentally to asymmetries of economic and political power that are constitutive
of the capitalist system of development, and indeed of world capitalism generally.
2. The asymmetries of economic and political power
that exist between groups of nations cannot be removed or significantly ameliorated within
the structures and strategic possibilities that are integral to the prevailing system of
capitalist accumulation.(5)
II. The Continuing Polarization
The polarization between the North and South is
more pronounced than it has ever been. The United Nations Human Development Report for
1997 shows that the share of world trade for the 48 least developed nations, representing
10% of the world's population, has halved in the past two decades to just 0.3%, with over
50% of all developing countries not receiving any foreign direct investment (two-thirds of
which went to just 8 developing countries).(6) In fact, around
100 developing and transition countries experience slow economic growth, stagnation, or
outright decline, and the incomes of more than a billion people now no longer reach levels
attained 10 or even 30 years ago. The same Report indicates that 1.3 billion people a day
live on a dollar a day or less, that there are 160 million malnourished children, that
one-fifth of the world's population is not expected to live beyond 40 (in some countries
life expectancy has fallen by 5 years or more), and that 100 million people in the North
live below the poverty line (the North also has 37 million jobless people). Well over a
billion human beings lack access to safe water, nearly a billion are illiterate, and
around 840 million experience hunger or food insecurity. The same report also shows that
the net wealth of 10 billionaires is worth 1.5 times the combined national incomes of the
48 least developed nations.(7) The
accomplishments of some nations in the face of such adversity are commendable and even
heroic: during 1980-95 Burkina Faso, Gambia, Senegal, and Zimbabwe reduced child mortality
by a third to a half in the face of declining incomes for much of this period, and
Algeria, Jordan, Peru, Syria, and Trinidad and Tobago by a half to two-thirds (the latter
nations despite reductions in per capita income of 20% or more over the last decade). But
the disparities between North and South are increasing dramatically, and this in the era
of globalization: the share in global income of the poorest 20% of the world's people has
fallen from 2.3% in 1960 and 1.4% in 1991 to a current level of 1.1%, while the ratio of
the income of the top 20% to that of the poorest 20% rose from 30:1 in 1960 to 61:1 in
1991, and grew still further to a figure of 78:1 in 1994.(8) These figures
point to a serious dilemma for the nations of the South. It is estimated that these
nations need to expand economically at a rate of around 6-7% annually for several years if
they are to provide employment opportunities for their expanding labour forces (growing at
about 3.5% a year in countries such as Brazil and Mexico), and if they are to hope to meet
their citizens' basic needs for food, shelter, clothing, health and education over a
twenty-year period.(9)
These trends show no sign of slowing down, even
though the United Nations estimates in The Human Development Report that it will
only take 1% of global income and around 2-3% of national income in all but the most
impoverished countries to fund a programme to eliminate world poverty.(10) Where the
subject of comparative international political economy is concerned, these stark and
appalling facts call for an account of the systemic international inequalities that are
their basis, and since the aim of the uneven development or dependency paradigm has always
been to furnish precisely such a theory, it has not lacked a prima facie rationale
even when some of its formulations have been questioned and found in whatever ways to be
lacking. The time is certainly right for a revisiting of this paradigm: global capitalism
as currently configured confronts less wealthy nations with severe, systemic, and pressing
problems, problems that only this paradigm has depicted and analyzed in a serious and
comprehensive way.
III. The Transnationalization of Financial
Capital: (1) the Situation of the Less-Wealthy Nations (and East Asia in Particular)
It is difficult to do full justice here to the many
facets of the epochal transformations that have taken place in extraterritorial financial
markets and institutions since the early 1980s.(11) But in noting
some of the more distinctive features of these shifts, it can be seen that in addition to
a tripling in the overall volume of transnational capital flows between 1980 and 1992,
there has been an equally marked change in the composition of the flows themselves,
especially to developing countries. Direct investment to developing countries nearly
doubled in the period from the early 1980s to the early 1990s, and in 1995 the East Asian
countries received an estimated $53.7 billion in foreign direct investment (FDI), up 24.7%
on 1994.(12)
However, portfolio capital investment to these countries developed even more
spectacularly, with a tenfold increase between 1990 and 1993, with East Asia being the
largest recipient. It should be noted, though, that flows of portfolio investment declined
from $84 billion in 1993 to $56 billion in 1995, with a particularly sharp fall taking
place in equity flows-- these dropped from $46 billion in 1993 to $22 billion in 1995.
This was due mainly to the rise in US interest rates in early 1994, the Mexican crisis a
year later, the US stock market surge in 1995 (a surge that has maintained itself pretty
consistently until the present time, viz. 1998), and concerns that the East Asian
economies were overheating in late 1995.(13) It is too soon
to say what impact the East Asian crisis will have on international portfolio investment
in the region (the Thai banking-system collapse that precipitated the crisis occurred as
recently as July 1997), but in the absence of the actual figures it seems pretty safe to
assume that the decline in portfolio investment that began prior to the collapse of the
East Asian economies has if anything been exacerbated by the crisis. It is important for
us to get a sense of the kinds of portfolio investment flow that have been moving in and
out of East Asia in these alternating phases of financial expansion and contraction, even
if only to form a notion of the character and magnitude of the current crisis, and what
this may portend for a new and modified version of the uneven development or dependency
paradigm.
Capital from bonds or fixed income securities
amounted to $800 billion in developing countries in 1995, about two-thirds of their equity
capitalization.(14)
Where the East Asian countries are concerned, the large direct flow of capital provided by
FDI noted above has been exceed in terms of growth rate by equity investment, which rose
from $2.6 billion in 1989 to approximately $12.2 billion in 1995. This represented about
55% of all portfolio equity flows to developing countries in 1995 (Latin America came next
with 28%). In 1994 foreigners made net purchases in East Asian stock markets that amounted
to $2.5 billion in South Korea, $1.3 billion in Malaysia, and $2.1 billion in Indonesia.(15)
This very substantial total private investment in
the East Asian countries has been made possible by important structural changes in the
financial markets themselves, and by the creation of several new instruments of
international finance in the last two decades or so-- largely because of liberalization
and also because of the emergence of completely new international markets for securities,
futures, options, swaps, international mutual funds, international bonds (these markets
were opened to developing countries in the 1990s), and American and global depository
receipts which gave American companies access to the stock markets of industrialized and
industrializing countries.(16) Part of this
development was a new interest shown by investors in Asian stock markets that led quickly
to a boom in the East Asian bourses: in 1993 alone the share indexes in Hong Kong grew by
116%, in Jakarta by 115%, and in Manila (the best Asian performer) by 154%.(17) The scale of
this very rapid growth can be indicated by a comparison, made by Ajit Singh, between the
relative times it took the United States and the emerging countries to reach roughly the
same capitalization ratios:
The speed of development of Third World stock
markets in the recent period may be judged from the fact that it took eighty-five years
(1810-1895) for the US capitalization ratio (market capitalization as a proportion of GDP)
to rise from 7 percent to 71 percent. In contrast, the corresponding Taiwanese ratio
jumped from 11 percent to 74 percent in just 10 years between 1981 and 1991. Similarly,
between 1983 and 1993 the Chilean ratio rose from 13.2 percent to 78 percent; the Korean
from 5.4 percent to 36.2 percent and the Thai from 3.8 percent to 55.8.(18)
At the same time the growing reliance of developing
countries on portfolio investment has also been instrumental in creating the structural
conditions responsible for the current collapse of the East Asian financial markets. To
begin with, there is the sheer disparity of scale between the combined resources of the
funds run by financial institutions in the most advanced industrial countries and the
market capital of middle-income countries very new to this form of capitalism. The
combined pool of funds managed by financial institutions in the high-income countries runs
to around $10-15 trillion, whereas the total market capitalization of all lower-income
countries (referred to by World Bank officials as 'emerging market' countries) is in the
order of $1 trillion.(19)
The effects of an imbalance of this kind during a rapid movement episode are potentially
catastrophic for a lower-income country, whose stock exchange is likely to be dominated by
foreign-owned portfolios (as has already been noted Manila's (for example) is 44%
foreign-owned). Furthermore, portfolio investors can pull out of markets very quickly, and
are prone to do so if short-term performance targets are not met or if other economic
indicators are thought to portend weakness (such as the high levels of non-performing
loans in East Asian banking systems that are said to have been instrumental in bringing
about the current crisis). This is especially true of the US mutual funds, which are
inclined to jettison their holdings if quarterly performance standards are not reached or
if there is the expectation of a falling market.(20) A third feature
of the new kinds of market capital that promotes instabilities of the kind now being seen
in Southeast Asia has to do with the disposition of short-term investment capital not to
reflect underlying economic 'fundamentals' such as output or employment.(21) A rise in US or
European interest rates, say, with no change whatsoever in the macroeconomic conditions of
the lower-income countries involved, can none the less induce a change of perception on
the part of foreign portfolio investors with holdings in the lower-income countries. The
result can be a swift reversal of investment flows as funds are channelled elsewhere in a
stock market stampede, with possibly devastating consequences for prices in the equity
markets of the poorer country thus affected. The behavior of this new form of short-term
portfolio capital is quite different from that of financial and industrial capital as
characterized by Marx, since the virtual autonomy it enjoys in relation to actual economic
activity (this being the primary source of its volatility) makes it correspond more to
what he calls 'fictitious capital' in Volume 3 of Capital, where it is used to
designate a form of capital that creates money in ways completely detached from the
productive process and the exploitation of labour.(22) Interestingly
enough, the only advice the World Bank and its representatives, Mohsin Khan in this case,
can give to lower-income countries faced with a potentially damaging reversal of portfolio
investment flow is the now familiar refrain: 'strive for consistency in the implementation
of strong macro-economic and structural policies, and ensure that borrowed resources are
appropriately invested'.(23)
A country facing significant withdrawals of foreign
portfolio capital will face the 'usual' problems resulting from pressure on its exchange
rates and its balance of payments (with a resulting drain on foreign-exchange reserves),
and from the almost inevitable price falls in domestic financial markets. This in turn can
result in a weakening of the lower-income countries financial system, which is more likely
if banks and financial houses are closely integrated with the securities sector, and have
borrowers with a high level of investment in the domestic market: these borrowers will
default on their repayments and leave the banks and financial houses facing shortfalls in
meeting their obligations, which they may then try to discharge by borrowing abroad.(24) In the longer
term, however, the lower-income country relying on relatively large inflows of short-term
capital provided by foreign portfolio investment (as opposed to foreign direct investment
which is harder to withdraw quickly), and thus facing the possibility of overnight capital
flight when financial markets become volatile, confronts a serious problem of
macroeconomic management encompassing but also extending beyond the phenomena-- runs on
its currency, interest-rate hikes, a balance of payments and foreign-reserves squeeze, and
so forth-- more immediately visible when capital-market volatility starts to become more
generally disruptive. For this instability makes it difficult for lower-income countries
to pursue independent fiscal and monetary policies and to have a coherent strategy for
managing exchange rates. This is especially so when the lower-income countries involved
have only very short periods of time in which to find workable realignments in vast and
unstable markets (in 1995 the portfolio investment market's world-wide transactions
amounted to $1.3 trillion daily or $312 trillion in a year of 240 business days.(25) Moreover, as was
evident during the exchange-rate instabilities after the ERM débâcle in 1992,
transnational capital markets are now large enough, and institutional speculators possess
sufficient resources that are swiftly interconvertible (banking, securities and insurance
businesses now blend into each other, as typified by the proposed $83 billion merger
between the second largest US commercial bank, Citicorp, and the financial conglomerate
Travelers Group (which is the US's third largest brokerage firm), as well as the
comprehensive transformation in the UK of what a decade ago used to be 'building
societies'), to neutralize the coordinated efforts of even the American and Western
European central bank during a financial crisis. Lower-income central banks, such as those
in Southeast Asia today, with resources that are a fraction of their G-7 counterparts,
have virtually no chance of succeeding where much bigger central banks have failed (and
will continue to do so in the absence of more permanent institutional arrangements to
control such instabilities).
Lower-income countries face a constant and
seemingly irremovable dilemma in this immense and fluid financial environment. To raise
standards in education, health-service provision, and social welfare they may have to
pursue an independent fiscal and monetary policy, but this will almost certainly result in
exchange-rate instability, and setting independent exchange-rate levels will likewise
cause the country in question to have less control over its domestic macroeconomic and
monetary arrangements. The three situations-- capital mobility, fiscal and monetary policy
autonomy and stable exchange-rates-- seem therefore to be mutually incompatible, leaving
countries, and especially lower-income countries, with little or no room for manoeuvre. In
addition, and the recent Asian economic crisis bears this out, portfolio funds, both
foreign and local, tend not to go into those sectors, manufacturing and agriculture
primarily, that take longer to produce significant yields, but instead find their way into
domains where options favoring 'quick' money are more readily available, namely, the stock
market and real estate.(26)
The ideal situation for such threatened lower-income countries would be for there to be a
multilateral strategy that is coordinated accordingly but which still allows a country to
use a range of capital controls that give it a degree of macroeconomic and monetary-policy
autonomy in the face of market integration.(27) But the
coordination of multilateral efforts to stem capital market instability is difficult to
sustain over the longer haul, when the crisis that prompted the initial search for
multilateral coordination has dissipated, and national self-interest asserts itself again
in the absence of institutional forces and principles strong enough (politically and not
just economically) to counter such fissiparous tendencies. And so the structural dilemma
remains: market integration places a high premium on the coordination of policies between
nations, but this coordination is harder to maintain in the longer term because there
seems to be no way of obviating tendencies to fall back on national self-interest when it
becomes more difficult to support coordinated macroeconomic and fiscal measures for more
than a just a relatively short span of time. Here of course the wealthier countries have a
huge advantage because they have a better chance of using their economic and political
resources to manage such crises in ways not available to their poorer counterparts: they
can use these resources to allow their fiscal and monetary policies to operate
independently in the short-term, and the policies they implement in this connexion are not
necessarily to the benefit of the less-wealthy nations (who in any case enjoy no such
freedom to decouple fiscal from monetary policy).(28) For example, the
'structural adjustment' package that South Korea had to accept as a condition of getting
its recent IMF bail-out will cause a significant rise in unemployment because the
government will have to lower or eliminate its subsidies to state-owned enterprises and
set high real interest rates to reduce Korea's current account deficit and keep the won
stable, but this does not seem to figure among the IMF's primary concerns, which, as in
everything else that comes under its purview, are to safeguard 'confidence' in the
international banking and trading systems and to preserve and promote access to markets
world-wide as an end in itself. Or, to mention another recent case, the Mexican economic
collapse in December 1994 was precipitated in part by high US interest rates imposed by
the Federal Reserve to prevent the US economy from 'overheating' and to help reduce the
size of the US's chronic current account imbalances-- with high US interest rates however
Mexico's debt situation became unmanageable and the peso went into a free-fall.(29)
IV. The Transnationalization of Financial
Capital: (2) Some Theoretical Considerations
The absence of a viable system for ensuring
adequate macroeconomic management in the face of financial market volatility is a problem
that is particularly pressing for lower-income countries. It is, however, the outcome of a
more profound failure that results from the convergence or intersection of two other
crises: the crisis that accompanied the ending of the 'Golden Age', when the social and
economic costs (inflation in particular) of Keynesian and New Deal/Great Society policies
intended to ensure that consumption was somehow always in line with production were found
to be 'unacceptable' by the Reagan and Thatcher administrations; and the succeeding
crisis, when the neoliberal switch of emphasis from fiscal to monetary policy (augmented
by an array of supply-side instruments) turned out to be too deflationary, so that
monetarism was abandoned in the early 1980s by its leading exponent, the British
Conservative government. Since then there has been no adequate system of national
macroeconomic management capable of producing sustained noninflationary growth, whether in
the USA or elsewhere, and the powerlessness of the less-wealthy nations in the face of
world financial market instabilities must necessarily be seen in this broader and more
encompassing context.(30)
The currently prevailing neoliberal ideology-- promulgated in the US but also espoused by
multilateral institutions such as the World Bank and IMF, and which accords priority to
keeping inflation low, to avoiding price 'distortions', to monetary discipline (though not
quite full-blown monetarism after the 1980s), and to deregulation and liberalization-- has
no solutions for capital market volatility beyond the pious injunction that the affected
countries should try always to have 'sound macroeconomic fundamentals' and embrace open
markets.(31)
The components of this ideology were seen by the World Bank and others as the enabling
basis of East Asia's 'miraculous' economic success, and the collapse of the economies of
Thailand, Indonesia, Malaysia, and South Korea (as well as Japan's lingering recession)
has exposed in the most abrupt and dramatic fashion this ideology's economic and political
limitations.(32)
It is in this context that a new and modified version of dependency theory has its place,
along with the notion that we may be on the threshold of the emergence of a new and
somewhat different regime of accumulation (though as yet it is of course too early to make
any predictions).
Whatever happens the claim, made by Giovanni
Arrighi and others, that Japan and the other East Asian economies constitute a formation
that has begun to supersede an American economic hegemony that has lasted for most of this
century, is one that can no longer be upheld in this bald and unqualified fashion, if at
all. For the immense proliferation of pension, insurance, and mutual funds in the last
decade or so has changed radically the circuits of realization and accumulation that are
at the disposal of the capitalist system, and the crisis of the East Asian economies is
arguably an outcome of this new state of affairs.(33) The impact of
these new circuits of realization and accumulation on the economies of the less-wealthy
nations has to be taken into consideration, especially since these nations are, as we have
seen, confronted unrelentingly by an ideology (the 'Washington Consensus' identified by
John Williamson) which insists that all economic advancement, including progress beyond
the most abject poverty and immiseration, has necessarily to be market-driven. And,
moreover, the question which lies at the heart of theories of dependency and uneven
development-- viz. the possibility of implementing a postcapitalist system of production
and accumulation-- can be answered only by an analysis of these new and very recent
capitalist circuits of realization and accumulation.
V. Portfolio Capital in Practice
As stated earlier, the sheer disproportion in the
relative sizes of the stock market capitalizations of the advanced industrial and the
so-called emerging countries affords the former group of nations more flexibility in
dealing with international capital market mobility. However, the scope for economy
policy-making in the less wealthy nations is constrained in another way, namely, by the
particular concentrations of accumulated assets in pension and mutual funds in the
advanced industrial countries, and especially by the business practices of the managers of
these funds, who are concerned solely with short-term dividends and not at all with the
economic and social well-being of the economies in which their funds are invested. And
these assets are huge. In 1994 two American pension funds alone-- the Teachers' Insurance
and Annuity Association-College Retirement Equities Fund (TIAA-CREF) and the California
Public Employees Retirement System (CALPERS)-- had assets of $140 billion and $100 billion
respectively, and the largest pension fund in the UK, the Post Office and British Telcom
Fund, had holdings of $35 billion. The total figure for world-wide pension fund assets in
1994 was $10 trillion.(34)
In the same year, 1994, the stock market capitalization of all emerging countries totalled
a mere $1.9 trillion, and the GDPs for all of the world's 51 low-income nations totalled
$1.2 trillion (only $392.6 billion if one excluded China and India).(35) The
disproportion between these pension funds and the less-wealthy nations, therefore, is
palpable if not staggering: pension funds in a handful of countries, with no account taken
here of mutual and insurance funds (insurance fund assets amounted to $2.6 trillion by the
end of 1994), dwarf the total 'wealth' of these less prosperous countries.
Moreover, the forms of capital associated with
pension, mutual, and insurance funds have done away with many of the traditional
disciplines exercised by ownership at the point of production: many of the financial
instruments created as part of the burgeoning of such funds are less amenable to
established disciplines and forms of regulation, and this because the instruments in
question are not positioned within relatively stable and organized markets in the ways
typical of more conventional forms of financial capital. These instruments are managed by
relatively few and largely anonymous fund managers, based overwhelmingly in the US, the UK
and a few other countries, and their complexity is often such that they tend to be
understood by only a few specialists. The inevitable outcome is (i) that the creators of
these novel, often hybrid instruments stand most to benefit from their deployment simply
because they are in a position to be maximally cognizant of their intricate workings; (ii)
that since many of these instruments are consciously designed to pass financial risks,
transaction costs, etc., from the lender to the borrower, Third World financial
institutions who borrow through them inevitably take higher risks than their lender banks
in the First World; and (iii) that, as with any financial-market innovation, the first
users of the mechanism or channel in question tend invariably to profit disproportionally
from it-- as these come to be more widely used the rates of their attendant gains are
inclined generally to fall. The power of those who control such funds and the instruments
and channels through which they are deployed is therefore immense, and these highly mobile
and relatively unconventional forms of capital are very much the engine of the newest
regime of capitalist accumulation.
But this expansion in its present forms of
transnational portfolio capital does not augur well for the development of the
less-wealthy countries. There is ample empirical evidence of direct correlations between
portfolio capital equity inflow and exchange rate instabilities; as there is of the
destabilizing 'income-effects' generated by stock-exchange volatility, of the failure of
portfolio inflows in developing economies to be matched by increases in aggregate saving
and investment in those countries, and of the propensity of stock markets to favor the
survival of large though relatively unprofitable firms at the expense of their smaller but
more efficient counterparts. Other difficulties exist: the proneness of financial markets
to failure (information deficits, unenforceable contracts, and so on); the inability of
the developing country relying on foreign portfolio capital to use this short-term and
speculative capital as part of a long-term macroeconomic strategy; and the susceptibility
of such capital to exogenous pressures (shifting US interest rates, the paramountcy of the
needs of advanced country investors, and so forth).(36)
But the most important consideration here is that
the transnational financial markets have done nothing so far (and neither do they give any
indication of doing so in future) to deal with what is perhaps the single most important
causal factor in the economic declines experienced by many Latin American and sub-Saharan
African countries in the 1980s, declines that in many cases are continuing into the 1990s
(of the 44 low-income countries in the 1996 World Development Report for whom such
information is available, 23 experienced a fall in the average annual growth of GNP per
capita during 1985-94, as did 22 of the 50 middle-income countries).(37) This is the
inability of the governments of the countries in question to maintain levels of real
investment: according to the 1991 World Development Report, gross domestic
investment grew negatively in the Latin American and sub-Saharan countries as a group in
the 1980s, and both groups experienced the largest declines in growth rate at the same
time.(38) Why
did real investment fall so significantly in these less-wealthy countries? And will the
exponential growth in transnational financial markets do anything to alleviate the
chronically low levels of investment (and output) in these nations? The answer to the
latter question, in the light of the evidence available so far, is 'no'. In fact, the need
of emerging countries to keep real interest rates high in the hope of attracting investor
funds from abroad by ensuring higher returns for foreign capital, and to fall in line with
the deflationary intent that is standard to all IMF/World Bank 'structural adjustment
programmes', will, all else being equal, lead to lower real wages. Given continuing high
levels of unemployment, this policy will inevitably have negative effects on that
country's income distribution. Given also the high existing levels of poverty, a growing
population, depressed wages (for the reason just indicated), uneven economic performance,
and other possible factors such as a decline in the quality of land stock (and the almost
certain depletion of environmental assets), there is certainly no way that the poorer
nations will be able to generate enough savings and investment endogenously to drive any
kind of real growth, and this even if they try to heed the World Bank's injunction to seek
their 'comparative advantage' (though many non-industrialized nations have no evident
'comparative advantage' to benefit from) and to maintain open trade and investment
arrangements (as the optimal way in its eyes to ensure such growth). Moreover, significant
amounts of foreign portfolio capital is not likely to flow in the direction of such
countries, even if they sought to implement open trade and market arrangements. The plight
of such countries is dire, and given the almost complete absence of institutions and
mechanisms designed at both the national and international level to promote long-term
investment and financial stability, continued stagnation is virtually inevitable for most
of these countries: many of them have already been consigned, in Samir Amin's words, to a
'Fourth World' that has no significant prospect of advancing even to the threshold of
industrialization and of benefitting in any way from current and future expansions of
international trade.(39)
The fundamental insight of dependency theory-- that all claims to the contrary
notwithstanding capitalism is not inherently 'progressive'-- appears to be more probative
than the cozening neoliberalism of those who insist that 'open' markets and the pursuit of
'comparative advantage' are somehow going to be the salvation of the world's low-income
countries.
VI. Dependency Theory Revisited via a Detour
Through Arrighi's Analysis of the Current World-System
Dependency theory has of course aimed to provide an
explanation for the systematic underdevelopment of the non-industrialized or
semi-industrialized nations (thereby filling a lacuna in marxist theories of imperialism,
which have tended to focus more on the contradictory nature of capitalist production and
its property relations and less on the politically instituted relations of exchange
between nations).(40)
Dependency theory has done more than this, however, because it has as one of its
corollaries the proposition that as long as actually existing capitalism prevails, the
low-income countries as a group are in principle not going to be the beneficiaries of any
structural changes in the international system. But if it is the case that the
less-wealthy countries are not going to benefit from any structural disposition of
the international system as long as actually existing capitalism continues to exist, then
it behoves the proponent of dependency theory to provide an account, however stylized, of
the current disposition of this system. To my mind, the most historically detailed and
analytically rigorous analysis of the current regime of accumulation, its relationship to
its predecessor regimes, and the conditions being set down now for its possible successor,
is the one furnished by Giovanni Arrighi in his The Long Twentieth Century: it
seems to me that any advocate of whatever version of dependency theory has at some point
to engage with the argument of this exemplary text.
One of Arrighi's aims is to account for the decline
in profitability and economic growth associated with the ending of the 'Golden Age' of the
western economies from the 1970s onwards. His primary analytical notion is that of a
'systemic cycle of accumulation'. Adapting Marx's formula for the basic circuit of
capital, moneycommoditiesmore money (MCM1), Arrighi argues that
each systemic cycle consists of two phases. One is a period of 'material expansion', in
which profits are derived largely from the production and traffic in commodities, and
which Arrighi takes to be the equivalent of the MC component of Marx's formula. The
other is a period of 'financial expansion', in which profits come primarily from financial
enterprises and not from the extension or intensification of the production and traffic in
commodities, and which Arrighi takes to be the equivalent of the CM1
segment of Marx's formula. Arrighi describes these expansions thus:
Material expansions occur because of the emergence
of a particular bloc of governmental and business agencies which are capable of leading
the system towards wider or deeper divisions of labour. These divisions of labour, in
turn, increase returns in capital invested in trade and production. Under these
conditions, profits tend to be plowed back into further expansion of trade and production
more or less routinely, and knowingly or unknowingly, the system's main centers cooperate
in sustaining one another's expansion. Over time, however, the investment of an
ever-growing mass of profits in the further expansion of trade and production inevitably
leads to an accumulation of capital over and above what can be reinvested in the purchase
and sale of commodities without drastically reducing profit margins. Decreasing returns
set in; competitive pressures on the system's governmental and business agencies
intensify; and the phase is set for the change of phase from material to financial
expansion.(41)
Arrighi identifies four major systemic cycles of
accumulation, or 'long centuries', in western capitalism: the Genoese, the Dutch, the
British, and the United States. He also thinks it possible that Japan/East Asia is on the
verge of constituting itself as a successor (fifth) major systemic cycle. In addition, he
identifies (in his response to Pollin) three different sources of financial profit that
have a particular role in the processes of financial expansion:(42)
(1) a source in which 'cut-throat intercapitalist
competition' creates excessive liquidity that finds an outlet in financial transactions.
(2) a source in which the significant
redistribution of income to capitalists creates conditions for the profitability of such
financial transactions.
(3) a source in which the liquidity generated by
this profitability moves from centers that are no longer capable of sustaining material
expansion to those that are developing this capability, thereby creating the conditions
for the supersession of the previous phase of financial expansion.
Arrighi says explicitly that 'all financial
expansions were eventually superseded by a new phase of material expansion'.(43) This may be true
of all systemic cycles of accumulation up to the present one-- on this I have no quarrel
with Arrighi (and Pollin for that matter). But unless this characterization of succeeding
phases and cycles is to be elevated into a teleology that runs a staunchly dialectical
course (a 'logic of world economic history' in the manner of Hegel(44)), the
possibility must be left open that there may be no recognizable successor systemic cycle
of accumulation to the present one, and that the primacy of the current systemic cycle may
thus extend indefinitely into the (so far anticipatable) future. Or for there to be a
series of transformations, however prolonged, of the current phase of financial expansion,
so that by the time this series of transitions has progressed far enough, there may no
longer be a form of capitalism that resembles the presently regnant and American-sponsored
systemic cycle, or indeed for there to be anything like a systemic cycle of accumulation
in the way characterized by Arrighi.(45) If these
scenarios were to obtain, then Marx's insight that the capitalist has no intrinsic
interest in the value of commodities he or she buys or finances so long as the commodities
in question can be sold for a profit will be borne out, and the blissfully 'utopic'
situation for the capitalist, whereby the capitalist moves directly from the initial sum
of money to yet more money (the circuit MM1), bypassing altogether the
production and exchange of commodities (the circuit MCM1), will have
materialized. If this new regime of accumulation should be implemented, then, pace
Arrighi and Pollin, this will be something that occurred without the accompanying impetus
to generate conditions for a new and succeeding phase of material expansion: there would
simply be an indefinitely ongoing process of financial expansion. But how is this
possible, given that profits necessarily have at some point to come from the production
and circulation of commodities? (This is not to suggest that there will no longer be any
material or commodity-production expansions if these scenarios were materialized-- a
material expansion may take place in future, but it will not do so according to the
ebb-and-flow logic outlined in The Long Twentieth Century.)
For Arrighi the two circuits or phases of capital
are in a relationship of oscillation: to put it somewhat schematically, when capitalists
can't make enough profits from commodity production or have over-accumulated as a result
of commodity production, they switch to financial transactions, and return to commodity
production (only) when the speculative bubbles generated by excessive financial expansion
have burst. In other words, Arrighi conceives of the relationship between phases as one of
succession or alternation, i.e. as an essentially temporal relationship. But a significant
body of work on recent international trade and financial regimes would seem to indicate
that the relationship between the financial and productive capital is now primarily
spatial, so that what we have in world capitalism today approximates more to a complex
amalgam of two simultaneously existing subregimes, one that is purely financial, and one
represented by commodity production and its attendant forms of productive capital.(46) The huge
disparity between the sizes of these subregimes needs to be emphasized again: not just the
scale of the pension, insurance, mutual and hedge funds noted in Section V above, but also
the sheer volume and value of trading on foreign exchange markets (the world's largest
financial market), which in 1994 was nearly 40 times the daily value of cross-border
trade.(47)
The international system of financial markets has
undergone a series of structural transformations since 1972, several of which are still
taking place.(48)
According to Randall D. Germain, these include changes in the sources of international
credit and a new capital recycling mechanism, and together they began a revolutionary
transformation in the 1980s that has effects which are still continuing. The changes in
the sources of international credit are well-known, but, says Germain, the more important
changes have taken place in the capital recycling mechanism, i.e. 'the form of credit made
available to the world economy, in the networks of monetary agents which control access to
this credit, and in the relationship between public monetary agents and private monetary
agents within the global financial system'.(49) As a result,
Germain goes on to say, a new era in international finance has emerged, one that can
appropriately be called 'decentralized globalization', and which is to be associated with
the enfranchisement of a whole range of new and not always disciplined systemic creditors(50), the rise
generally of unstable institutional arrangements(51), the diminished
authority and effectiveness of state and public monetary institutions (except when it came
to leading the way in deregulating financial markets(52)), the
complementary growth in the authority and effectiveness of private monetary institutions
(towards whom the balance of power has now gravitated), and the changing of the criteria
used to govern access to flows of mobile capital (these have moved in favor of the
interests of private agents(53)). While private
institutions have grown in importance, the state continues to have a role since capital
mobility is not perfect, in at least two respects. One is that the state still possesses a
degree of macroeconomic policy autonomy, though this room for manoeuvre is nonetheless
circumscribed by the global integration of financial markets and by the propensity of
states in this situation to allow private agents use of their policy instruments in ways
which effectively make these agents proxies for state and public authority. The second is
the preeminence enjoyed by the American, German, and Japanese governments and their
policies in determining the course and constitution of global financial markets, and
allied with this is the systemic centrality enjoyed by the financial markets in New York,
Tokyo and London. But this state capability notwithstanding, today no single state or
public authority has effective control of the international financial system, which was
not the case in Arrighi's two most recent systemic cycles of accumulation, the US and the
British, which gave markets in New York and London a clear and decisive primacy in those
systems of accumulation. The result is a growing regionalization of interest rates and the
declining importance of reserve requirements as financial institutions become more
hybridized and their resources more interchangeable as a result.(54)
There is no unitary, comprehensive model of how
this global financial system (which can appropriately be viewed as an MM1
subregime) relates to the production and exchange of commodities (which constitutes a CM1
subregime). The dynamics of the relation between these two subregimes as it involves the
economic system of a particular country (or group of countries) or region is inflected by
path dependency, so that the economic activities that form this particular dynamic
necessarily occur within, and have outcomes that are determined by, an always specific
structure of political and social relations, a structure which that country or
group of countries may or may not share with other countries or groups of countries.(55) Some countries--
Hong Kong and Singapore come readily to mind because their economies hinge crucially and
overwhelmingly on the provision of financial services and the undertaking of a variety of entrepôt
functions-- display a very substantial embeddedness in the financial subregime or circuit
of capital MM1, whereas other countries-- Taiwan or Brazil are good
examples-- which are much more dependent on manufacturing are more profoundly embedded in
the commodity-production subregime or circuit of capital CM1, and still
others-- the United States (especially) and Japan-- evince a powerful embeddedness in both
of these subregimes. The forms of embeddedness in these subregimes are inevitably somewhat
stylized in this account, since there is no such thing as a pure or perfect regime of
financial enterprises nor one of commodity-production. And since there is in principle a
potential multiplicity of forms of path dependency and embeddedness, different countries
can relate in very different ways to one of both of these subregimes. But what of the
claim, made by Arrighi and Pollin that (in the latter's words) 'the MM1
circuit of pure financial deals operates successfully only because this operation always
presupposes a newly successful MCM1 circuit'?(56)
In the account be canvassed here, the financial
capital subregime (FCSR) can stand in a variety of relationships to the productive
capital subregime (PCSR), and each such relationship will have its own particular
dynamism, though it will certainly be possible for us to categorize the different kinds of
relationship and their accompanying dynamism, and to formulate principles that govern the
relationships and dynamisms under consideration. In dealing with Pollin's question (albeit
as filtered through our nomenclature), a great deal will depend on whether the FCSR
happens to be in a relation of subordination or superordination to the PCSR. In a
capitalist order, the survival or continued viability of this or that FCSR or PCSR
is wholly contingent on the capacity of that particular subregime to generate
continued surpluses. Failure to do this would amount to a crisis for that subregime and
for the capitalist system which it embodies. This is the only absolute necessity incumbent
upon any system or form of accumulation as long as capitalism prevails. To continue to
extract surpluses a regime has to enable its agents or instruments to find outlets or
markets into which these surpluses can be channelled. Determining the subordination or
superordination of an FCSR in relation to a PCSR will therefore require a
determination to be made of their respective (and always path dependent capacities) to
generate surpluses.
Judged on the basis of the respective scale of the
surpluses they have generated, there is compelling evidence that since the end of the
'Golden Age' (and especially more recently) FCSR and not PCSR has been the
primary capitalist subregime. To cite some evidence from Doug Henwood:
From 1982, the beginning of the great bull market,
until 1989, the end of the LBO era, the market value of nonfinancial corporations' stock
rose $1.83 billion (from $1.38 trillion to $3.21 trillion), and the value of corporate
bonds outstanding rose $519.1 billion (from $407.0 billion to $926.1 billion). But while
stocks rose 133%, and bonds, 128% (and of course most of the gain in bonds was the result
of new issues, not capital gains on old ones), business sector productivity rose 12.6%,
and the broadest productivity measure of all, real GDP per hour worked throughout the
entire economy (including government and nonprofit sectors), rose 6.3%-- quite weak by
historical standards.(57)
The primacy of FCSR over PCSR in the
last two decades or so is palpable, and so is the fact, given growth of this magnitude,
that surpluses are being recycled into financial expansion and not (so much) into
commodity-production. With generally weak levels of productive output, the threat of an
immense over-abundance of commodities being left unsold is thereby reduced-- and it is
this threat which lies at the heart of the insistence (which shows itself in Pollin's
question) that financial capital can continue to have life only if the system of
accumulation it subserves maintains or increases productive output (i.e. incorporates a
'successful MCM1 circuit'). Of course commodities 'have' to be produced,
but in the current system of accumulation this is being left to the low labour-cost
economies who function therefore as suppliers for the markets of the high-income
countries. Arrighi himself notes this when he says that '[the] main structural feature of
the emergent [East Asian] regime remains the provisioning of wealthy markets with products
that embody the cheap labor of poor countries'.(58) But he then goes
on to say that
Nevertheless, the "informality" and
"flexibility" of the Japanese multilayered subcontracting system, combined with
the abundance of parsimonious and industrious labor in the East Asian region, endow
Japanese and East Asian capital with a distinctive advantage in the escalating global race
to cut labor costs. It is precisely in this sense that the emerging East Asian regime of
accumulation is a negation of the old US regime. (p. 348)
However, it is clear that there is no such 'global
race' (let alone one that is 'escalating') to cut labour costs, since the foreign direct
investment that targets such low-cost labour in developing countries is being aimed at
very specifically at a tiny minority of countries: as was indicated above (in note 37),
the World Bank's figures show that two-thirds of the world's FDI goes to a mere 8
less-developed countries, and that 50% of the 93 less-developed countries receive little
or none. There is a quest for low-cost labour, while some features of its general
trajectory may conform to the one delineated by Arrighi, it is not one that is by any
means global: on the contrary, the search or 'race' for cheap labour has a marked regional
structure (Africa and most of Latin America are effectively disqualified from
participation from the outset), and its direction within that structure is even more
highly selective. The quest for cheap labour subserves the imperative of stocking the
markets of the wealthy nations, granted, but the over-accumulations of the wealthy nations
are not allowed to saturate commodity-producing domains located in low-income countries
(i.e. domains which belong to the PCSR): instead, in the currently prevailing
capital allocation mechanism these surpluses are plowed-back into dealings on world-wide
financial markets (the FCSR), and when surpluses do find their way to the
less-wealthy countries, they do so through the intermediation of these financial markets,
which means that they can be pulled-out of the low-income countries at extremely short
notice.
Attention also needs to be paid to the entirely new
configurations of speculative and industrial or commercial capital that now exist: many
corporations nowadays derive profits from speculation as well as the enterprises they are
more standardly associated with, and so the need to look for outlets for surpluses in new
commodity-producing circuits is less pressing. For instance, since 1993 American Airlines
has been hawking its own mutual fund in conjunction with its frequent-flier programme; and
in the US the quasi-federal agencies, the Federal National Mortgage Association ('Fannie
Mae') and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation ('Freddie Mac') buy up mortgage loans
from banks and thrift societies and package these into bonds that are then sold on the
securities market (a process therefore known as securitization, and which was responsible
for $1 trillion in outstanding securities in 1996).(59) Money continues
to be invested in a few developing countries of course, with East Asia being the primary
beneficiary until its economic collapse. But even here the traffic is almost entirely
one-way: in 1994, foreign direct investment accounted for 50% of East Asia's net capital
flow, and portfolio investment for a further 24%; foreign direct investment moved from
$1.3 billion (10% of net capital flows) in 1980 to $43 billion (or 50%) in 1994, and
portfolio investment grew from nil to $18 billion (or 24% of capital flows) in the same
period.(60)
(East Asia's current crisis can be attributed in
part to this almost complete reliance on foreign capital, especially on the part of the
so-called 'second-tier' East Asian newly industrialized countries (Indonesia, Malaysia and
Thailand). Arrighi does quite plausibly say that the centers of the emerging regime of
accumulation will receive a surge of foreign capital drawn to them by the prospect of
higher rates of profit than those available at the centers of the declining system. But
the heavy reliance of the East Asian countries on foreign investment possesses several
troubling features that immediately qualify any judgement of them as the (collective)
potential successors of the dominant but ostensibly fading US regime. In 1991-3 Malaysia
had an annual average ratio of foreign direct investment to Gross Domestic Capital
Formation of 24.6%. This also accounted for its high 1995 services account deficit ($6.7
billion), caused by foreign companies repatriating their profits. Malaysia also has a
problem with low total factor productivity, which grew at an annual rate of only 2.2%
between 1991 and 1996. At the same time Malaysia has seen a massive credit expansion,
averaging over 30% a year between 1994 and 1997, and constituting around 160% of its GDP,
with bank loans alone approaching 57% of GDP. In Thailand, every $1 exported contains 43
cents of imported materials, so dependent are its export-oriented manufacturing sectors on
imported parts. Thailand also has a large foreign debt total of $90 billion. Indonesia had
a foreign debt total that stood at $60 billion at the time of its 1997 IMF bailout.
Nonperforming loans in the Southeast Asian banking system amount to approximately $73
billion, over 13% of Southeast Asian GDP.(61) These therefore
hardly seem like nations belonging (with Japan) to the regime of accumulation seen by
Arrighi and many others as the potential successor to the possibly declining United States
regime.(62))
Together, the features that most strongly define
actually existing world-capitalism point inexorably to the relative autonomy of financial
(and 'fictitious') capital from productive capital, that is, the autonomy of the FCSR
from the PCSR. The embeddedness of a national economy in either or both of these
subregimes is strongly path dependent, and this may, for the economy of that particular
nation, either enhance or reduce the autonomy of the FCSR in relation to the PCSR,
or vice versa. But in reality there is no such thing as an absolute autonomy or an
absolute integration of these subregimes: financial capital markets and regimes and
productive capital markets and regimes are necessarily related to each other, and this
because funds are free to move between them, and policies made in regard to the one
necessarily affect the other.
At the same time the world-capitalist system that
has emerged since the end of the 'Golden Age' is in a condition of crisis, and this
because the surpluses yielded by the FCSR enable those national economies most
deeply embedded in it to escape many of the disciplines that are imposed on those
economies which function by being embedded primarily in the PCSR (let alone the
stark inequities that confront those in the 'Fourth World' that belongs to neither
subregime). The most telling illustration of this is the recent 'accomplishment' of the US
in eliminating the massive fiscal deficits incurred during the Reagan and Bush
administrations, thanks largely to tax revenues garnered from the current stock-market
boom (stocks on the New York Stock Exchange rose in value by 33% in 1997)-- only a country
as widely and powerfully embedded in the FCSR subregime as the US is today can
afford itself this option (which must make the US-- now able to comport itself as the
'investor aristocracy' of this world-capitalist system-- an object of envy for many a poor
country struggling with its fiscal deficits but with no financial-market resources at hand
to bring it this kind of miraculous relief(63)).
World-wide economic polarization in its current
manifestation is driven more by the divorce (always politically instituted and maintained)
between financial and productive capital, and less by the mechanisms of unequal exchange
as typically understood in dependency theory. In the typical account, unequal exchange
exists because of an international division of labour which allows the industrial
countries to commandeer industrial productive capacity while consigning low-income
countries to the production of primary commodities (this being the phenomenon of
compulsory maldevelopment described by Samir Amin and others in the dependency and uneven
development school), because international trade on these terms can never be mutually
advantageous. However, in the account being canvassed here, while there still is unequal
exchange-- it being undeniable that even in the era of financial capital (and its
fundamental divorce from productive capital) the less-wealthy countries function
essentially as producers of primary commodities and as providers of cheap labour-- the
main source of international economic polarization today is precisely the autonomy of
finance capital from productive capital. This autonomy establishes asymmetries between the
high- and low-income countries that appear to be deeply entrenched, and so the question
remains whether, and if so to what degree, these asymmetries are surmountable.
VII. Surmounting International Economic
Polarization
The development-policy prescriptions-- trade and
price liberalization, deregulation, privatization, and closer links with the world
economy-- of international financial institutions such as the World Bank and the IMF, as
well as those nations, primarily the United States, who underwrite the neoliberal
'Washington Consensus', are largely irrelevant to the economic situation of the
lower-income countries, many of whom are still struggling with varying degrees of success
to make the long-term structural adjustments necessitated by the major recession and debt
crisis of the 1980s.(64)
For these institutions and wealthy countries swimming with the tide of global economic
integration is the only way forward for the nations of the South. The dependency and
uneven development paradigm has long been associated with the proposed delinking of the
economies of the South from those of the North.(65) This delinking
strategy is commended because of the conviction of those who uphold this paradigm that the
situation of the lower-income countries cannot be improved structurally within the terms
of the prevailing regime of accumulation. As we have seen, a judicious scrutiny of the
available evidence is hardly likely to controvert this conviction. More recently, Lance
Taylor, who has made a number of careful criticisms of the World Bank over the years but
who is hardly to be regarded as a marxist, has recommended a partial delinking on
'narrowly technical grounds'.(66) Taylor has
analyzed extensively the data regarding the open trade and capital market strategies of a
cross-section of 50 lower-income countries (going as far back as the economically more
propitious 1960s) and found few gains and some losses accruing from these
exogenously-oriented policies. He proposes that these countries should dispense on a
piecemeal basis with linkages to the markets of the North that bring 'the least benefits'
or exact 'the greatest costs', concluding that a limited and selective autarky of this
kind offers them a better bet for economic survival-- as Taylor puts it, 'the inwardly
oriented resource allocation strategy seems the least risky, especially for large
countries' (p. 141).(67)
Given that openness to global capital flows makes a
lower-income country more vulnerable to external shocks and to the onset of financial
crises such as the one now occurring in Southeast Asia, it would seem to be in the best
interests of the lower-income countries to buck the wisdom of the neoclassical consensus
and attempt a strategic and selective delinking along the lines recommended by Lance
Taylor. This would at least place the less-wealthy countries in a better position to exert
greater control over their macroeconomies as they implement development policies that are
endogenously oriented, as opposed to placing their faith in roller-coaster markets that
have the lower-income countries at their mercy. With this kind of control, and more
democratic political institutions, they can at least pursue more consistently, if not more
seriously, the project of an economic liberation that hopefully will start to bring to an
end the newest form of economic dependency.
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
NOTES
1. On the 'Golden Age', see
Stephen A. Marglin and Juliet B. Schor, eds., The Golden Age of Capitalism :
Reinterpreting the Postwar Experience, Oxford 1990. See also Charles P. Kindleberger,
'Why Did the Golden Age Last So Long?', in his The World Economy and National Finance
in Historical Perspective, Ann Arbor 1995, pp. 163-80. For an account of the course
taken by the advanced capitalist countries in the succeeding decade, the 1980s, see Andrew
Glyn, 'The Costs of Stability: The Advanced Capitalist Countries in the 1980s', New
Left Review 195(1992), pp. 71-95.
2. For such skeptical arguments
about the 'openness' of the world economy, see David Gordon, 'The Global Economy: New
Edifice or Crumbling Foundations?', New Left Review, 168(1988), pp.24-64; and Paul
Hirst and Grahame Thompson, 'The Problem of "Globalization": International
Economic Relations, National Economic Management and the Formation of Trading Blocs', Economy
and Society 21(1992), pp. 357-96. It should be noted though that Gordon's data only
goes up to 1984 (the world's economy has certainly become more open since then), and that
Hirst and Thompson seem to think that 'globalization' is only truly so if it involves the
elimination of the state, which of course has not ceased to exist and to be effective in
international economic management, and from which state of affairs they conclude
mistakenly that there is no true globalization. Robert Pollin derives the terms 'Golden
Age' and 'Leaden Age' from the writings of Joan Robinson. See his 'Contemporary Economic
Stagnation in World Historical Perspective', New Left Review 219(1996), pp. 109-18.
3. For recent accounts of these
problems with the development paradigm, see David L. Blaney, 'Reconceptualizing autonomy:
the difference dependency theory makes', Review of International Political Economy
3(1996), pp. 459-97; and Jan Nederveen Pieterse, 'Dilemmas of Development Discourse: The
Crisis of Developmentalism and the Comparative Method', Development and Change
22(1991), pp. 5-29, and 'The development of development theory: towards global criticism',
Review of International Political Economy 3(1996), pp. 541-64. I use the terms
'developed', 'less developed', 'underdeveloped', etc., in a suitably cautious way,
especially since they have had such a problematic intellectual and political lineage: as
many critics of these notions have pointed out, there is no underlying economic teleology
for any developmental path, and, moreover, 'development' is too easily conflated
with 'economic growth' per se (thereby occluding the question of the impact of such growth
on human well-being, the role of women in production, the environment, and so on). I am
sympathetic towards attempts at providing a less tainted nomenclature, but since I want to
engage fairly directly with this established intellectual tradition, I have decided to
retain the familiar though troubled and troubling lexicon it has developed over the course
of several decades. I shall however complement it with the triptych high income
('core')-middle income ('semiperipheral')-low income ('peripheral') countries, as
standardly used by world-system theorists, with the caveat that this triptych too is not
without its problems.
4. Especially important here are
the views of those who maintain that the important consideration in analyzing the
functions of the state in economic development is the politics of the regimes,
institutions, classes, and groupings that are inserted into this or that state-process or
state-project-- the state being anything but a static form or edifice that can be
counterpoised to 'markets' or 'multilateral institutions' or 'transnational corporations',
etc. See, for instance, Bruce Cumings, 'The Origins and Development of the Northeast Asian
Political Economy: Industrial Sectors, Product Cycles, and Political Consequences', in
Frederic Deyo, ed., The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism, Ithaca
1987, pp. 44-83; Chalmers Johnson, 'Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The
Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan', in Deyo, ed., pp.
136-64; Deyo, Beneath the Miracle: Labor Subordination in the New Asian Industrialism,
Los Angeles and Berkeley 1989; Sylvia Maxfield, Governing Capital: International
Finance and Mexican Politics, Ithaca 1990; Jung-en Woo (now Meredith Woo-Cumings), Race
to the Swift: State and Finance in Korean Industrialization, New York 1991; William
Reno, Corruption and State Politics in Sierra Leone, Cambridge 1995; and Mahmood
Mamdani, Citizen and Subject: Contemporary Africa and the Legacy of Late Colonialism,
Princeton 1996.
5. For useful general discussion
of these two principles and their implications, see, inter alia, Arturo Escobar, Encountering
Development: The Making and Unmaking of the Third World, Princeton 1995, Jorge
Larrain, Theories of Development: Capitalism, Colonialism and Dependency, Cambridge
1989, Colin Leys, The Rise and Fall of Development Theory, Bloomington 1996, and
John Toye, Dilemmas of Development: Reflections of the Counter-Revolution in
Development Economics, Oxford 1993 (2nd ed.).
6. United Nations Development
Programme, Human Development Report 1997, Oxford 1997, passim.
7. The claim that the net worth
of 10 billionaires is 1.5 times the combined national income of the 48 least developed
nations is the focus of an article titled 'Seven richest could end world poverty' by Larry
Elliott and Victoria Brittain in the Manchester Guardian Weekly, June 22, 1997. The
Human Development Report estimates that the cost of its proposed $80 billion
anti-poverty programme could be covered by the wealth of seven billionaires. The
'structural adjustment' programmes advocated by the International Monetary Fund and the
World Bank for developing countries require the wholesale elimination of expenditure on
education, health, and social services, and this in countries that may be experiencing a
decrease in the years of average life expectancy!
8. Thus, in 1994, the GNP per
capita in Rwanda and Mozambique was $80 and $90 respectively, and in the US $25,800, Japan
$34,630, and Switzerland $37,930. Average life expectancy at birth in Mozambique was 46
years (no figures were available for Rwanda), in the USA 77 years, Switzerland 78 years,
and Japan 79 years. See the World Bank's World Development Report 1996, Oxford
1996, pp. 188-9
9. These points are made by Ajit
Singh, from whom these figures are taken, in his 'The Actual Crisis of the 1980s: An
Alternative Policy Perspective for the Future', in A.K. Dutt and K.P Jameson, eds., New
Directions in Development Economics, Aldershot 1992, pp. 104ff. Singh also notes that
virtually throughout the 1980s, a decade of economic recession, the Latin American and
African countries made net resource transfers to the developed countries, rather than vice
versa: in 1984-85 alone the Latin American and African countries transferred $40 billion
and $5 billion respectively to the developed nations.
10. The claim that 1% of global
income is all that is needed to eliminate poverty world-wide is perhaps unrealistic, given
the complex causal relationship between economic factors and human capacities that has to
be taken into account in any characterization of poverty. The Human Development Report
tries to reflect this complexity by having two sets of indices of poverty ('income
poverty' and 'human poverty'), but this only emphasizes the difficulties involved in
making plausible the claim that global poverty can be eliminated by expending 1% of the
world's income.
11. See Stephany
Griffiths-Jones and Barbara Stallings, 'New global financial trends: implications for
development', in Stallings, ed., Global Change, Regional Response: the new
international context of development, Cambridge 1995, pp. 143-73. The data in this
paragraph is taken from this article. See also Laurence Harris, 'International Financial
Markets and National Transmission Mechanisms', in J. Michie and J. Grieve Smith, eds., Managing
the Global Economy, Oxford 1995, pp. 199-212; and S. Sen 'On Financial Fragility and
its Global Implications', in Sen, ed., Financial Fragility, Debt and Economic Reforms,
Basingstoke 1996, pp. 35-59. A good summary of the changes that have taken place in global
financial markets in the last two decades is to be found in Griffith-Jones, 'Regulatory
Implications of Global Financial Markets', in Sen, ed., Financial Fragility, pp.
174-97.
12. World Bank, World Debt
Tables: External Finance for Developing Countries, Washington DC 1996, p. 93. East
Asia is also the largest source of FDI to developing regions, with a 1993 outflow of $4.6
billion.
13. World Bank, World Debt
Tables: External Finance for Developing Countries, p. 4.
14. See Griffith-Jones and
Stallings, 'New global financial trends', p. 162. Mohsin S. Khan, 'Recent Developments in
International Financial Markets', Asian Development Review, 13(1995), p. 47, points
out that almost $60 billion in bonds was issued in 1993, the third successive year in
which bond issues doubled in relation to the preceding year. (Though there was a sharp
fall from this 1993 peak after the Mexican economic crisis at the end of 1994.) The IMF's Private
Market Financing for Developing Countries, Washington DC 1995, says that the
tightening of US monetary policy earlier in the year caused a market instability that
reduced private financing to developing countries, but that most countries had recovered
by the middle of 1995 (p. 2). In 1994 developing countries placed $58.8 billion in bonds,
despite the financial crisis of that year.
15. See the individual country
tables in the World Debt Tables: External Finance for Developing Countries.
16. Doug Henwood, Wall
Street, London 1997, is a readable and informative account of many of these new
financial instruments and the markets in which they operate. See also Griffiths-Jones and
Stallings, 'New global financial trends', p. 153; and Mohsin Khan, who notes that trade in
interest rate swaps alone grew from $0.7 trillion in 1987 to $1.5 trillion by the second
half of 1991. The combined assets of pension funds in France, Germany, Japan and the
United Kingdom stood at around $5.7 trillion by the end of 1991. According to the Manchester
Guardian Weekly, 9 November 1997, the US now has more than 2,800 mutual funds
controlling over $4 trillion, with $220 billion being placed in them in 1996 alone (nearly
double the 1995 total of $242 billion. At the time of the October 1987 crash there were
only 812 US mutual funds managing s total of $242 billion. The World Bank estimates that
the combined portfolios of US pension funds, mutual funds and insurance companies amounted
to $8 trillion in 1994. On the 'short-termism' of pension fund managers, see also Richard
Minns, 'The Social Ownership of Capital', New Left Review 219(1996), pp. 42-61.
Keynes's of course had already made a famous critique of stock-market 'short-termism' in
Chapter 12 of The General Theory in 1936.
17. Asian Bank, Asian
Development Outlook 1994, Oxford 1994, p. 18. The Asian Bank of course welcomed the
processes of liberalization that led to the surge in portfolio investment.
18. Ajit Singh, 'Portfolio
Equity Flows and Stock Markets in Financial Liberalization', Development 40(1997),
p. 23. Singh also makes the point that in 1992 there were 6700 companies quoted on the
Indian stock market, compared with 7014 companies in the US, 1874 in the UK, and 665 in
Germany. In addition, the 'average daily trading volume on the Bombay stock market has
been about the same as that in London-- about 45,000 trades a day' (p. 23).
19. Mohsin Khan, 'Recent
Developments', p. 50. Henwood, Wall Street, p. 16, provides a table which shows
that while the UK, Japan, and the USA had in 1994 shares of world stock market
capitalization that amounted to 8%, 24.5%, and 33.5% respectively, the share for the
emerging world totalled a mere 12.7%: Malaysia had 1.3%, Taiwan 1.6%, Thailand 0.9%, the
Philippines 0.4%, Korea 1.3%, and Indonesia 0.3% of world stock market capitalization that
year. The East Asian crisis will almost certainly necessitate a downward revision of these
figures (taken by Henwood from International Finance Corporation, Emerging Stock
Markets Factbook 1995).
20. Mohsin Khan, 'Recent
Developments', p. 50. Khan is a World Bank official, and I have deliberately chosen to use
his assessment of the impact of extraterritorial financial markets on the lower-income
countries, since this assessment makes plain aspects of liberalization and deregulation
that do not accord with the encomiums that stream from the Bank where programs of
liberalization and deregulation are concerned.
21. The capacity of presentday
stock markets to deviate from 'fundamentals' for considerable periods of time is found not
only in the stock exchanges of the emerging countries but also in the established stock
markets of London and New York. On this, see Ajit Singh, 'Portfolio Equity Flows', p. 24.
22. For the notion of
'fictitious capital', see Marx, Capital, Moscow 1967, vol 3, part V. See also
Suzanne de Brunhoff, 'Fictitious Capital', in J. Eatwell, M. Milgate and P. Newman, eds., The
New Palgrave Marxian Economics, New York and London, 1990, pp. 186-7. Laurence Harris
has invoked this notion to explain the highly autonomous character of presentday
transnational capital markets. See his 'Alternative Perspectives on the Financial System',
in Harris, J. Coakley, M. Croasdale and T. Evans, eds., New Perspectives on the
Financial System, London 1988. 80% of all foreign transactions involve a round-trip of
a week or less, and most take place within a single day. For this, see James Tobin,
'Prologue', in M. ul Haq, I. Kaul and I. Grunberg, eds., The Tobin Tax: Coping with
Financial Volatility, Oxford 1996, p. xii.
23. Khan, p.52. Granted that
there is no consensus on the effects created in host country financial markets by rises in
foreign interest rates are concerned. There is also no consensus on the specific impact of
foreign portfolio investment on domestic country exchange rates, especially expected
exchange rates. Empirical work is still in its relatively early stages, and a few studies
of the Mexican collapse of December 1994 have only just appeared in the last couple of
years. One study that shows a correlation between the inflow/outflow of portfolio
investment into Mexico and the behavior of US interest rates is Ilene Grabel, 'Marketing
the Third World: The Contradictions of Portfolio Investment in the Global Economy', World
Development 24(1996), pp. 1761-76. The often highly complex transaction mechanisms for
these new markets have not been around for very long, and information on them is still
scarce and incomplete. It will be interesting to see what similar empirical studies of the
current Southeast Asian crisis will reveal in this regard. A more judicious assessment
than Khan's of the potential problems posed by transnational portfolio capital of this
kind is given in R. Devlin, R. Ffrench-Davis and S. Griffith-Jones, 'Surges in Capital
Flows and Development: An Overview of Policy Issues', in Ffrench-Davis and Griffith-Jones,
eds., Coping with Capital Surges: The Return of Finance to Latin America, Boulder
1995, pp. 225-60.
24. See Griffith-Jones and
Stallings, 'New global financial trends', p. 164.
25. For these figures, see
James Tobin, 'Prologue', p. xvi. According to the World Bank, in 1990 there were 232
emerging market funds throughout the world, with net assets totalling $13.7 billion. By
mid-1995 these had increased nearly sixfold, with estimated net assets of about $123
billion. See World Bank, World Debt Tables: External Finance for Developing Countries,
p. 20.
26. In 1995 Malaysia had a
services account deficit of $6.7 billion (20 billion ringgit) due mainly to foreign
companies repatriating profits from their investments. For this see the Far Eastern
Economic Review, December 12, 1997, p. 65. The propensity for 'fast money' to
gravitate towards property development and speculation is borne out by the fact that in
Kuala Lumpur, the capital of Malaysia, the volume of newly-constructed office space in
1997 alone exceeded the volume for the whole of the preceding ten years, and the supply of
retail space in 1998 will represent a rise of 140% from 1995 levels. For this see the Far
Eastern Economic Review, May 15, 1997, p. 86. Doug Henwood, p.111, cites data provided
in United Nations Centre on Transnational Corporations, World Investment Report 1991,
which shows that in the late 1980s transnational direct investment grew at 2-3 times the
rate of trade, whereas in the 1970s and early 80s the growth rates of the two had been in
rough parity.
27. On the inconsistent triad
of capital mobility, stable exchange-rates, and monetary policy independence, see Benjamin
J. Cohen, 'Phoenix Risen: The Resurrection of Global Finance', World Politics
48(1996), pp.268-96. On the thesis that in principle capital mobility disposes governments
to seek a multilateral cooperative framework for monetary and fiscal policy adjustments,
see also David M. Andrews, 'Capital Mobility and State Autonomy: Toward a Structural
Theory of International Monetary Relations', International Studies Quarterly
38(1994), pp.193-218; and Andrews and Thomas D. Willett, 'Financial Interdependence and
the State: International Monetary Relations at Century's End', International
Organization 51(1997), pp. 479-511. There is an ample literature indicating,
globalization notwithstanding, national governments do have room to make macroeconomic
policy changes that stabilize overseas capital flows. See, inter alia, Laurence Harris,
'Financial Markets and the Real Economy', in S. Sen, ed., Financial Fragility, pp.
60-72; and John B. Goodman and Louis W. Pauly, 'The Obsolescence of Capital Controls?:
Economic Management in an Age of Global Markets' World Politics 46(1993), pp.
50-82. Goodman and Pauly make the argument that there not be a separation between
(longer-term) foreign direct investment and (short-term) portfolio capital since the
political arrangements devised to deal with the latter will have implications for the
former (p. 81).
28. Andrews and Willett,
'Financial Interdependence and the State', p. 487, make the relevant point that the United
States can pursue fiscal policies that cause significant fluctuations in the dollar,
whereas the course taken by the dollar on international currency markets rarely affects US
fiscal policy. Few other countries enjoy the luxury of being able to overlook to such a
degree the impact of fiscal policy on their currencies and vice versa. The greater
economic flexibility afforded wealthy countries such as the United States was noted over
50 years ago by Albert Hirschman in his National Power and the Structure of
International Trade, Berkeley 1945. For the problems small states encounter when
international markets are able to constrain domestic economic policy, see Peter J.
Katzenstein, Small States in World Markets, Princeton 1985.
29. There were of course other
factors at work in the Mexican collapse, not least the vast amounts of foreign equity
capital that flowed into Mexico in the 1990s-- between 1992 and 1994, the average annual
capital inflow rate was 8% of GDP (as opposed to 5% of GDP during the previous peak in
1977-81). The share price index in the Mexican stock market rose from 250 in 1989 to 2500
in 1994, even though its average annual GDP growth rate between 1990 and 1994 was only
2.5%, and even though Mexico's current account deficit in 1993 was $20 billion,
representing 6% of GDP (it rose to 9% of GDP in 1994). On the matter of high interest
rates, it should be acknowledged that the Bundesbank was also pursuing a policy of high
interest rates in the early 1990s. After the collapse, Mexico's real GDP fell by 7% in
1995, and that in Argentina by 5% through a 'knock-on' effect. For this, see Ajit Singh,
'Portfolio Equity Flows', p. 26. The similarities between Mexico and Argentina and some of
the East Asian countries two years later are easy to notice.
30. The much-vaunted US
expansion of the 1990s is less impressive when put in perspective. The average annual
increase of GDP in real terms (adjusted for inflation) up to the end of the third quarter
of 1997 has been a mere 2.2% since the previous peak in 1990. The two decades that
succeeded the ending of the 'Golden Age', the 1970s and 80s, by contrast saw annual growth
rates of approximately 2.75% and 2.95% respectively. The two decades of the 'Golden Age',
the 1950s and 60s, experienced annual growth rates of 3.5% and 4.5% respectively. For
these figures, see Jeff Madrick, 'Computers: Waiting for the Revolution', The New York
Review of Books, March 26, 1998, p. 29. Japan is now in its sixth year of recession,
and the Western European nations still face high levels of unemployment and low growth
rates.
31. These 'market-friendly'
injunctions are contained in the World Bank's influential 1991 World Development
Report: The Challenge of Development, Oxford 1991, see especially p. 5. The
already-mentioned Human Development Report 1997, after chronicling the widening gap
between wealthier and poorer countries (a gap that has a great deal to do with the
inhospitability poorer countries experience, 'systemically', at the hand of international
trade regimes that use 'free trade' and 'open markets' as shibboleths), still brings
itself to commend the market as a solution to the plight of the poor: 'Market competition
offers an important way in which people, especially poor people, can escape economic
domination by exploitative government, big landlords and big retailers' (p. 102).
32. For the World Bank's
assessment of East Asia's economic success, see its publication The East Asian Miracle:
Economic Growth and Public Policy, Oxford 1993. Robert Wade provides a fascinating
account of the ways in which this Report was gerrymandered to fit the terms of the Bank's
neoliberal ideology in his 'Japan, the World Bank, and the Art of Paradigm Maintenance: The
East Asian Miracle in Political Perspective', New Left Review 217(1996), pp.
3-36. The Bank's recent World Development Report 1997, Oxford 1997, backtracks on
its earlier and sheerly ideological hostility to the state, but tries to show that state
intervention, whose effectiveness in some cases the Bank now grudgingly acknowledges, is
none the less compatible with 'market-friendliness'. As Lance Taylor has noted in his
'Editorial: The Revival of the Liberal Creed-- the IMF and the World Bank in a Globalized
Economy', World Development 25(1997), pp. 145-52, there have been other recent
changes in the World Bank's policy disposition: the already-noted 'recognition of the
importance of at least functional public intervention' and 'the need to provide supporting
revenues; realization that controls on external capital movements and prudential
regulation can help contain financial fragility; abandonment of the doctrine that raising
the local interest rate will stimulate saving and thereby growth; initiatives to roll over
or forgive the bulk of official debt owed by the poorest economies'. At the same time,
Taylor rightly believes that the Bank is still some way short of adopting policies that
fully support the economic advancement of lower-income countries. A very similar
assessment is to be found in Ajit Singh, 'Openness and the Market Friendly Approach to
Development: Learning the Right Lessons from Development Experience', World Development
22(1994), pp. 1811-23, who provides trenchant criticism of the Total Factor Productivity
model that underlies the Bank's approach to developing countries. This model, says Singh,
unrealistically assumes 'full employment of resources and perfect competition, none of
which obtain in the real world. Moreover, it is a wholly supply-side model which ignores
altogether the role of demand-factors' (p. 1813). The problem with Singh's argument,
however, is his belief that the institutional basis for the Japanese model of economic
growth was replicated by Taiwan and South Korea, with Indonesia and Malaysia possibly
following close behind. The latter part of this claim will appear wildly implausible to
anyone with first-hand experience of the corruption-ridden bureaucracies of Indonesia and
Malaysia.
33. For Arrighi, see The
Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power, and the Origins of Our Times, London 1994, and
'Workers of the World at Century's End', Review 19(1996), pp. 335-51. Though
Arrighi is careful to acknowledge that 'it is not at all clear whether the emergent
Japanese leadership can actually translate into a fifth systemic cycle of accumulation'
(p. 335). I shall argue below that it is possible that the emerging or next system of
accumulation may not be one that can be understood in terms of a national hegemony that
makes intelligible or plausible the notion of a leadership exercised in these terms by
Japan or anyone else. The view that the rise of the East Asian nations has started to put
an end to US economic supremacy is complemented in some quarters by the conviction that
their emergence as economic powers also effectively discredits dependency theory, which of
course maintains that nations outside the capitalist 'core' like the East Asian economies
find it structurally difficult if not impossible to leave behind their initial
'peripheral' or 'semiperipheral' developmental situations. For such a view, see Richard F.
Doner, 'Limits of State Strength: Towards an Institutional View of Economic Development', World
Politics 44(1992), p. 398; and Gary Hawes and Hong Liu, 'Explaining the Dynamics of
the Southeast Asian Political Economy: State, Society, and the Search for Economic
Growth', World Politics 45(1993), p. 630.
34. For these figures, see
Minns, 'The Social Ownership of Capital', p. 43. Given the prolonged stock market boom of
the last two and a half years, these asset-totals can be presumed to be even larger. Minns
indicates that apart from the US and UK, the bulk of other pension fund holdings are to be
found in Japan, the Netherlands, Ireland, Argentina, Peru, Columbia, and a few other South
American countries.
35. The total for emerging
nations with stock markets is taken from Henwood, p. 16. These countries are: Malaysia,
South Africa, Chile, Taiwan, Thailand, Philippines, Korea, India, Mexico, Brazil,
Indonesia, and China. The GDP totals for low-income nations are taken from the World
Bank's World Development Report 1996, Oxford 1996, p. 210. The World Bank
classifies a low-income nation as one with a GNP per capita of $725 or less in 1994, a
middle-income country as one whose GNP per capita in 1994 was more than $725 but less than
$8,956, and a high-income nation as one with a GNP per capita that exceeded $8,956 in
1994.
36. In this connection Lance
Taylor has noted that '[half] the people and two-thirds of the countries in the world lack
full control over their own economic policy. Expatriate "experts" managed by
industrial country nationals and based in Washington DC regulate their macroeconomics,
investment projects, and social spending'. See his 'Editorial: The Revival of the Liberal
Creed', p. 145.
37. World Development Report
1996, pp. 188-9. By contrast, of the 21 high-income countries for which information is
available, only 2 (Finland and Austria) experienced a decline in their average annual GNP
per capita during 1985-94. Germany was the only high-income nation for which information
was unavailable-- reunification in 1991 makes any such computation unviable. The dismal
trading position of many low-income nations must also be taken into account: in the
ten-year period before 1996 the ratio of trade to GDP actually declined in 44 out of 93
less-developed countries, with two-thirds of the world's FDI going to a mere 8
less-developed countries, and with 50% of the 93 less-developed countries receiving little
or none. On this see World Bank, Global Economic Prospects and the Developing Countries
1996, Washington DC 1996, passim.
38. On this, see Albert
Fishlow, 'Economic Development in the 1990s', World Development 22(1994), p. 1826.
Fishlow makes the point that the World Bank has consistently ignored the issue of income
distribution, emphasizing instead the question of higher productivity, and I am indebted
to his account in the rest of this paragraph.
39. Yilmaz Akyüz and Charles
Gore, 'The Investment-Profits Nexus in East Asian Industrialization', World Development
24(1996), pp. 461-70, emphasize the importance in East Asian growth of overall capital
accumulation and the role of government in speeding it up. Many analysts, including the
World Bank, have tended to stress the importance of resource allocation for East Asian
industrialization, at the expense of the interactions between profits and investment.
Without wanting to generalize the East Asian model, the importance of profits and
investment for growth highlighted by Akyüz and Gore puts in even plainer relief the
predicament of many low-income nations, who simply do not have the resources to invest in
growth. For Amin see his Capitalism in the Age of Globalization: The Management of
Contemporary Society, various translators, London 1997. In my characterizations of
uneven development and the 'theorizations' of it provided by marxists, I have had Amin's
pioneering work most in mind, though I have of course tried to remain aware of the
differences between him and other members of this tradition.
40. It is precisely for this
reason that Ernesto Laclau regarded dependency theory as a deviation from marxism:
according to him it eschews analysis of the mode of production and the relations of
production (for Laclau the heart of marxism) in favor of the analysis of the system of
exchange between nations. See his 'Feudalism and Capitalism in Latin America', New Left
Review 67(1971), pp. 19-38.
41. Giovanni Arrighi,
'Financial Expansions in World Historical Perspective: A Reply to Robert Pollin', New
Left Review 224(1997), p. 155. I take this description of his position from Arrighi's
somewhat heated response to a review of his book by Robert Pollin. See Pollin,
'Contemporary Economic Stagnation in World Historical Perspective', New Left Review
219(1996), pp. 109-18. I don't mean to adjudicate in this exchange, and merely use part of
Arrighi's response because it contains an excellent summary of the position he sets out in
The Long Twentieth Century.
42. 'Financial Expansions', p.
157.
43. 'Financial Expansions', p.
157. Pollin agrees with Arrighi on this point (that all financial expansions are succeeded
by their material counterparts) in 'Contemporary Economic Stagnation', pp. 115ff.
44. That no such Hegelian Weltgeist
is at work in Arrighi's architectonic is clear from his insistence that 'sustained
financial expansions materialize only when the enhanced liquidity preference of capitalist
agencies is matched by adequate "demand" conditions'. On this, see 'Financial
Expansions', p. 156. For Arrighi these 'demand' conditions arise only when there is
interstate competition for mobile capital. The gist of my position however is that the
current regime of accumulation is one that makes financial expansion possible without the
promptings of interstate competition (a notion Arrighi gets from Weber) since (a) the
overwhelming majority of states are in no position structurally to join this competition
even at the most rudimentary level; and (b) the new kinds of capital come in a
bewilderingly different number of forms (which are often hybridized) and move at such
velocities that states cannot 'compete' for them in the old ways. Even the World Bank, for
all its enthusiasm in fostering what it takes to be competitive trade and markets, can do
no more than enjoin lower-income countries who are anxious to attract such capital to
'keep exchange rates favorable' and have 'sound macroeconomic fundamentals'. Though
well-meant, such prefectural advice is simply gratuitous, and akin to the injunction that
the pupils should 'give it a go' when competing in the school three-legged race. But the
World Bank's vapidity in this context is profoundly symptomatic: there is virtually
nothing that most states can do at present to create 'adequate "demand"
conditions' for mobile capital. And yet this is the era of a prodigious expansion of
financial capital....
45. Arrighi considers roughly
similar scenarios in his 'Epilogue' to The Long Twentieth Century when he outlines
three possible outcomes that may transpire in the event of a supersession of the US regime
of accumulation (pp. 354-5). First, the US may use its military and political power to
retain the surplus capital that would otherwise go to a new Centre of accumulation, in
which case it would become 'a truly global world empire'. Second, East Asian capital may
supersede the American regime, but since the new regime would not have the military and
global political power of its predecessor, 'the underlying layer of the market economy
would revert to some kind of anarchic order'. Third, capitalist history may be terminated
by the growing violence that its various orders have spawned in the last six hundred
years. The argument broached in the final part of this paper poses an alternative to these
three scenarios. It maintains that a polynucleated, multi-spatial regime of global
capitalist accumulation now prevails, one premised on different and sometimes quite
radical degrees of separation between Marx's two primary forms of capital, namely,
productive capital and finance (or financial) capital. The term 'finance capital' does not
however occur in Marx's oeuvre; but chapter 27 of Volume III of Capital
('The Role of Credit in Capitalist Production') was the basis of the fuller elaboration of
the concept in Hilferding's Finanzkapital. Marx though did suggest that there were
two ways of extending the means of credit available to industrial capital that correspond
in brief outline to Hilferding's two notions of productive capital and finance capital.
46. There is a problem in
mapping the distinctions made in this paper on to Arrighi's distinction between the
'material phase' MC and the 'financial phase' CM1 of a systemic
cycle of accumulation. Pollin suggest that Arrighi's renditions of Marx's formulas are
problematic because they 'obscure the logic operating in both phases', viz., that more
money (profits) must ensue at the end of each of these processes. This may be so. In this
paper, however, the distinction between 'productive capital' and 'financial capital'
refers not so much to two alternating phases as to two different spatial configurations or
logics for the organization of capital. Consequently, 'productive capital' and 'financial
capital' do not map easily on to (Arrighi's) MC and CM1
respectively, and I use 'productive capital' and 'financial capital' rather than his
formulas in giving my account.
47. Eric Helleiner, 'The world
of money: The political economy of international capital mobility', Policy Sciences
27(1994), p. 295. The volume of transactions on foreign exchange markets more than
quadrupled between 1986 and 1992, and the daily total reported gross turnover rose from
$932 billion in April 1989 to $1,354 billion in April 1992, a rise of 35%. For these
figures, see Barry Eichengreen, International Monetary Arrangements for the 21st
Century, Washington DC 1994, p. 61. Eichengreen also notes that the volume of net
daily foreign exchange transactions now exceeds the total official reserves of all IMF
member countries combined (p. 64). The IMF had 178 member nations by December 1993
(Eichengreen's time of writing).
48. In what follows I adhere
closely to the overviews presented in Randall D. Germain, The International
Organization of Credit: States and Finance in the World-Economy, Cambridge 1997,
Michael C. Webb, The Political Economy of Policy Coordination: International Adjustment
Since 1945, Ithaca 1995, and Adam Harmes, 'Institutional investors and the
reproduction of neoliberalism', Review of International Political Economy 5(1998),
pp. 92-121. Harmes is especially good on the shifts that have taken place in investment
allocation criteria with the emergence of the new financial markets.
49. Germain, p. 136.
50. Even those who write about
international financial markets from a neoliberal perspective believe that there is a
problem today with inadequately supervised markets. See for instance Ethan B. Kapstein, Governing
the Global Economy: International Finance and the State, Cambridge MA 1994, p. 183.
51. Here it is important to
note that the rise of instability is not necessarily to be equated with a scaling-down of
international coordination. As Michael Webb points out, if anything there has been more
coordination in the international economy since they 1970s, though it has not managed to
provide levels of stability previously reached. See The Political Economy of Policy
Coordination, pp. 252ff.
52. There is a good account of
this development in Eric Helleiner, States and the Reemergence of Global Finance: From
Bretton Woods to the 1990s, Ithaca 1994, which stresses the preeminent role of the
state in fostering the integration and deregulation of markets, and in Goodman and Pauly,
'The Obsolescence of Capital Controls?', pp. 50-82, who use a more dialectical approach
which sees government policy leading to increased integration and mobility, and this new
situation then leading private agents to press for even more deregulation.
53. As Webb puts it,
'governments have preferred to take their chances with unpredictable burdens imposed by
private markets responding to national policy differences, rather than coordinate in order
to reduce the likelihood and magnitude of future international market pressures' (pp.
259-60).
54. On this, see Germain, p.
161.
55. The importance of path
dependency is recognized in Pollin, 'Contemporary Economic Stagnation', p. 117.
56. Pollin, 'Contemporary
Economic Stagnation', p. 116. This question is posed because it is important for Arrighi
and Pollin, though, as will be seen, it is not necessary for us to answer it if we think
of the relation between financial capital and productive capital in terms other than those
of alternation or succession.
57. Henwood, p. 183. The
situation since 1989 has been very similar. To quote Henwood again: 'In 1991, finance,
insurance, and real estate, collectively nicknamed "FIRE", surpassed
manufacturing's contribution to GDP, and widened their lead in 1992 and 1993; as recently
as 1985, FIRE was 15% smaller. In 1993, manufacturing accounted for $1.1 trillion of
output, and finance for $1.2 trillion. Gross investment was $882 billion-- meaning finance
'produced' 34% more than the savings it theoretically channeled into investment' (p. 76).
58. The Long Twentieth
Century, p. 348.
59. On American Airlines see
Harmes, 'Institutional investors', p. 112; and for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, see
Henwood, p. 91. Henwood's book is a remarkable source of information for anyone interested
in the myriad new and different ways in which the current capital recycling mechanism now
works.
60. On this see World Bank, Managing
Capital Flows in East Asia, Washington DC 1995, pp. 7-8.
61. These details are discussed
in my unpublished paper 'The East Asian Economic Crisis'.
62. See The Long Twentieth
Century, pp. 325-56, for Arrighi's assessment of East Asia's economic advance, made of
course prior to the 1997 collapse of the region's economies. My claims here, and the
accompanying critique of Arrighi, will need to be revised once a clearer sense is had of
the less-immediately visible effects of the 1997 East Asian crash. Arrighi is right to
emphasize the importance of 'cheap-labour seeking investment' in promoting regional
growth, but account also needs to be taken of the path-dependent structural sensitivity of
the industrial policies of the Southeast Asian governments to what was happening in
Northeast Asia in the mid-1980s. On this structural sensitivity, see Jomo, K.S., et al., Southeast
Asia's Misunderstood Miracle: Industrial Policy and Economic Development in Thailand,
Malaysia, and Indonesia, Boulder and Oxford, 1997, p. 160.
63. I take the term 'investor
aristocracy' from Harmes, 'Institutional investors', p. 114, where it is used to designate
those workers who may have belonged to a 'labour aristocracy' in the days of the
Keynesian/New Deal economic dispensation, but who (in considerably smaller numbers) are
now transformed into investors by the succeeding phase of accumulation. It is important to
note that an effective state-formation is a prerequisite for the US's successful
channelling into the fiscal system of tax revenues harvested from stock-exchange
speculation. The role of the state as the forcing-house par excellence for securing
tax revenues has been stressed by Max Weber and Michael Mann. For Mann, see 'The
Autonomous Power of the State: Its Origins, Mechanisms, and Results', in John A. Hall,
ed., States in History, Oxford 1986, pp. 109-36. See also John M. Hobson, The
wealth of states: A comparative sociology of international economic and political change,
Cambridge 1997, especially pp. 252-3. Marxists need to engage more strenuously with this
neo-Weberian approach to the state-system if they are to analyze satisfactorily the
ensemble of substructures that make up the FCSR.
64. See Ajit Singh, 'The Actual
Crisis of the 1980s', p. 110.
65. See especially Samir Amin, Delinking:
Towards a Polycentric World, London 1990, and Carlos Diaz-Alejandro, 'Delinking North
and South: Unshackled or Unhinged?', in A. Velasco, ed., Trade, Development and the
World Economy: Selected Essays of Carlos F. Diaz-Alejandro, Oxford 1988, pp. 72-121.
66. Lance Taylor, 'Economic
Openness: Problems to the Century's End', in Tariq Banuri, ed., Economic
Liberalization: No Panacea (The Experiences of Latin America and Asia), Oxford 1991,
pp. 91-147.
67. In 'The Rocky Road to
Reform: Trade, Industrial, Financial and Agricultural Strategies', in A. de Janvry, S.
Radwan, E. Sadoulet and E. Thorbecke, eds., State, Market and Civil Organizations: New
Theories, New Practices and their Implications for Rural Development, Basingstoke
1995, pp. 86-111, Taylor has analyzed several results from the adoption of the
prescriptions enshrined in Washington Consensus, and concludes that they have only been
barely successful as a reform package, not infrequently providing a combination of 'high
interest rates, stagflation, deregulation and financial crashes'. This leads him to
suggest that LDCs would be better-off not underwriting capital markets and choosing
instead state-provided credit channelled through development banks or made available
directly by the government. Taylor concludes that 'the Bretton Woods institutions...
remain impervious to the fact that the invisible hand plus a minimal government
(especially in its fiscal, regulatory and investment roles) do not necessarily act
together to support sustainable economic growth' (p. 96). Emphasis Taylor's.
|